Skip to content

2023 European Tax Policy Scorecard

52 min readBy: Sean Bray, Alex Mengden

Introduction

The structure of a country’s taxA tax is a mandatory payment or charge collected by local, state, and national governments from individuals or businesses to cover the costs of general government services, goods, and activities. code is a determining factor of its economic performance. A well-structured tax code is easy for taxpayers to comply with and can promote economic development while raising sufficient revenue for a government’s priorities. In contrast, poorly structured tax systems can be costly, distort economic decision-making, and harm domestic economies.

These economic dynamics apply at the supranational level as well. While the power to tax is in the hands of European Union (EU) Member States, the EU’s long-term political goals, including facilitating the green and digital transitions,[1] managing the effects of Russia’s war in Ukraine, and possible enlargement will be expensive and require additional government revenue. Additionally, the Union will face increasing debt payments for the NextGenerationEU package adopted during the COVID-19 pandemic. As the EU takes a more active approach in both indirect and direct taxation to pay for these priorities and proposes new Own Resource ideas for the EU budget, it is important for policymakers to have a data-driven approach.

Furthermore, in line with tax provisions of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union,[2] EU tax policy is geared towards the smooth functioning of the single market. Harmonization can have more benefits than costs if the harmonized policy is a principled policy and not simply the least common denominator. Therefore, it is imperative to design Union policy with an eye towards current Member State policies to avoid creating more losers than winners from the common policy.

The variety of approaches to taxation among European countries creates a need to evaluate these systems relative to each other. For that purpose, we have developed the European Tax Policy Scorecard—a relative comparison of European countries’ tax systems.

The European Tax Policy Scorecard (ETPS)

The European Tax Policy Scorecard seeks to measure the extent to which a country’s tax system adheres to two important aspects of tax policy: competitiveness and neutrality.

A competitive tax code is one that keeps marginal tax rates low. In today’s globalized world, capital is highly mobile. Businesses can choose to invest in any number of countries throughout the world to find the highest rate of return. This means that businesses will look for countries with lower tax rates on investment to maximize their after-tax rate of return. If a country’s tax rate is too high, it will drive investment elsewhere, leading to slower economic growth. In addition, high marginal tax rates can impede domestic investment and lead to tax avoidance.

Table 1. 2023 European Tax Policy Scorecard Rankings

CountryOverall RankOverall ScoreCorporate Tax RankIndividual Taxes RankConsumption Taxes RankProperty Taxes RankCross-Border Tax Rules Rank
Estonia1100258116
Bulgaria2923261010
Switzerland389.49141311
Cyprus488.8483321
Latvia587.71614614
Malta680.729124213
Czech Republic780.31171279
Slovak Republic87520315528
Luxembourg974.725282145
Lithuania107461316723
Hungary1173.28432194
Sweden1271.6121820912
Turkey1371.217235226
Romania1470.971272720
Netherlands1569.6262110143
Croatia1666.852425431
Slovenia1765.41311232718
Finland1864.61419181719
Germany1964.527307107
Norway2064.31822211311
United Kingdom2162.4282026192
Denmark2260.71526171027
Austria2360.5242992315
Belgium2460.51915132526
Greece2560.1219312124
Poland2656.92310292429
Iceland27551616242930
Ireland2852.91027281732
Spain2952.63125113017
Italy3048.62217303222
Portugal3144.53231191425
France3244.5303222258

Stay informed on the tax policies impacting you.

Subscribe to get insights from our trusted experts delivered straight to your inbox.

Subscribe

According to research from the OECD, corporate taxes are most harmful for economic growth, with personal income taxes and consumption taxes being less harmful. Taxes on immovable property have the smallest impact on growth.[3]

Separately, a neutral tax code is simply one that seeks to raise the most revenue with the fewest economic distortions. This means that it doesn’t favor consumption over saving, as investment and wealth taxes do. It also means few or no targeted tax breaks for specific activities carried out by businesses or individuals.

As tax laws become more complex, they also become less neutral. If, in theory, the same taxes apply to all businesses and individuals, but the rules are such that some groups of businesses or individuals can change their behavior to gain a tax advantage, this undermines the neutrality of a tax system.

A tax code that is competitive and neutral promotes sustainable economic growth and investment while raising sufficient revenue for government priorities. There are many factors unrelated to taxes which affect a country’s economic performance. Nevertheless, taxes play an important role in the health of a country’s economy.

To measure whether a country’s tax system is neutral and competitive, the ETPS looks at 39 tax policy variables. These variables measure not only the level of tax rates, but also how taxes are structured. The ETPS looks at a country’s corporate taxes, individual income taxes, consumption taxes, property taxes, and the treatment of profits earned cross-border. The ETPS gives a comprehensive overview of how developed countries’ tax codes compare, explains why certain tax codes stand out as good or bad models for reform, and provides important insight into how to think about tax policy.

The ETPS is intended to focus on European Union Member States. However, it also includes European OECD countries that are not part of the European Union, but tend to have significant economic relationships with the EU—such as Iceland, Norway, Switzerland, Turkey, and the United Kingdom—to give policymakers in Brussels a better understanding of tax policies in those countries and the effects their decisions may have on important regional partners.

The ETPS uses the most up-to-date data available as of July 2023. Recent changes in countries making rapid reforms may not be reflected in this year’s version of the European Tax Policy Scorecard.

2023 Rankings

Estonia has the highest ranking tax code in the ETPS. Its top score is driven by four positive features of its tax system. First, it has a 20 percent tax rate on corporate income that is only applied to distributed profits. Second, it has a flat 20 percent tax on individual income that does not apply to personal dividend income. Third, its property taxA property tax is primarily levied on immovable property like land and buildings, as well as on tangible personal property that is movable, like vehicles and equipment. Property taxes are the single largest source of state and local revenue in the U.S. and help fund schools, roads, police, and other services. applies only to the value of land, rather than to the value of real property or capital. Finally, it has a territorial tax systemA territorial tax system for corporations, as opposed to a worldwide tax system, excludes profits multinational companies earn in foreign countries from their domestic tax base. As part of the 2017 Tax Cuts and Jobs Act (TCJA), the United States shifted from worldwide taxation towards territorial taxation. that exempts 100 percent of foreign profits earned by domestic corporations from domestic taxation, with few restrictions.

While Estonia’s tax system is the most competitive in the ETPS, the other top countries’ tax systems receive high scores due to excellence in one or more of the major tax categories.

Bulgaria has a flat personal income tax of 10 percent, a corporate income taxA corporate income tax (CIT) is levied by federal and state governments on business profits. Many companies are not subject to the CIT because they are taxed as pass-through businesses, with income reportable under the individual income tax. with a low rate of 10 percent, and relatively good cost recoveryCost recovery is the ability of businesses to recover (deduct) the costs of their investments. It plays an important role in defining a business’ tax base and can impact investment decisions. When businesses cannot fully deduct capital expenditures, they spend less on capital, which reduces worker’s productivity and wages. for machinery, as well as a broad based value-added tax (VAT) covering 96 percent of final consumption.

Switzerland has a relatively low corporate tax rate of 19.7 percent, a low, broad-based consumption taxA consumption tax is typically levied on the purchase of goods or services and is paid directly or indirectly by the consumer in the form of retail sales taxes, excise taxes, tariffs, value-added taxes (VAT), or an income tax where all savings is tax-deductible. , and an individual income taxAn individual income tax (or personal income tax) is levied on the wages, salaries, investments, or other forms of income an individual or household earns. The U.S. imposes a progressive income tax where rates increase with income. The Federal Income Tax was established in 1913 with the ratification of the 16th Amendment. Though barely 100 years old, individual income taxes are the largest source of tax revenue in the U.S. that partially exempts capital gains from taxation.

France has the least competitive tax system in the ETPS due to its multiple distortionary property taxes with separate levies on estates, bank assets, financial transactions, and a wealth taxA wealth tax is imposed on an individual’s net wealth, or the market value of their total owned assets minus liabilities. A wealth tax can be narrowly or widely defined, and depending on the definition of wealth, the base for a wealth tax can vary. on real estate. The French tax burden on labor of 47 percent for the average single worker is among the highest for ETPS countries and is steeply progressive, causing high efficiency costs. France’s VAT covers less than 40 percent of final consumption, revealing both policy and enforcement gaps.

Portugal has the second-least competitive tax system in the ETPS. It has a high corporate tax rate of 31.5 percent, including multiple surtaxes. Its corporate tax incentives feature both a patent boxA patent box—also referred to as intellectual property (IP) regime—taxes business income earned from IP at a rate below the statutory corporate income tax rate, aiming to encourage local research and development. Many patent boxes around the world have undergone substantial reforms due to profit shifting concerns. regime and the highest implicit R&D subsidies at a rate of 35 percent. Portugal also levies a high top tax rate on personal income at 53 percent while its 23 percent VAT rate only applies to half of the potential consumption tax baseThe tax base is the total amount of income, property, assets, consumption, transactions, or other economic activity subject to taxation by a tax authority. A narrow tax base is non-neutral and inefficient. A broad tax base reduces tax administration costs and allows more revenue to be raised at lower rates. .

Countries that rank poorly on the ETPS often levy relatively high marginal tax rates on corporate income or have multiple layers of tax rules that increase complexity. Four of the five countries at the bottom of the rankings have higher-than-average combined corporate tax rates, between 25 and 31.5 percent. Ireland ranks poorly on the ETPS despite its low corporate tax rate. This is due to high personal income taxes, worldwide taxation of dividends at high rates, and a relatively narrow VAT base. The five lowest-ranking countries have unusually narrow VAT bases, covering only between 44 and 53 percent of final consumption. They also tend to have higher than average top personal income tax rates, between 47.2 and 54.6, compared to an ETPS average of 40.1 percent.

Corporate Income Tax

The corporate income tax is a direct taxA direct tax is levied on individuals and organizations and cannot be shifted to another payer. Often with a direct tax, such as the personal income tax, tax rates increase as the taxpayer’s ability to pay increases, resulting in what’s called a progressive tax. on corporations’ profits. All European ETPS countries levy a tax on corporate profits, but the tax rates and bases vary significantly across countries.

The ETPS breaks the corporate income tax category into three subcategories. Table 2 displays each country’s corporate income tax category rank and score, along with the ranks and scores of the subcategories—namely, the corporate rate, cost recovery, incentives, and complexity.

Combined Top Marginal Corporate Income Tax Rate

The top marginal corporate income tax rate measures the rate at which each additional euro of taxable profit is taxed. Countries with higher top marginal corporate income tax rates than the ETPS average receive lower scores than those with lower, more competitive rates.

Malta levies the highest top corporate income tax rate (35 percent),[4] followed by Portugal (31.5 percent) and Germany (29.94 percent). The lowest top marginal corporate income tax rate among ETPS countries is in Hungary (9 percent), followed by Bulgaria (10 percent) and Ireland (12.5 percent). The ETPS’s average combined corporate income tax rate is 21.16 percent for 2023.[5]

Table 2. Corporate Taxes

CountryOverall RankOverall ScoreRate RankRate ScoreCost Recovery RankCost Recovery ScoreIncentives/Complexity RankIncentives/Complexity Score
Belgium1963.82449.7556.81774.8
Bulgaria393.6296.92039.71100
Croatia581.3771.7653.4891.3
Cyprus482.83892634.71588.8
Czech Republic1173.9868.62139.6791.4
Denmark1568.41959.22534.9496.9
Estonia297.61265.41100693.6
Finland1472.61265.42733.5399.8
France30432847.11145.53135.4
Germany27503034.21046.41873.9
Greece2162.11959.23126.51489
Hungary875.711003226.12761.7
Iceland1666.31265.42239.21676.4
Ireland1074.23892930.22270.5
Italy22612940.9365.32072.1
Latvia11001265.411001100
Lithuania680.3581.1463.52662.4
Luxembourg2555.62349.91245.12565.4
Malta2945.63218.313441189.5
Netherlands26552747.21542.22171.3
Norway1864.21959.22831.21289.5
Poland2360.7868.61741.52853.7
Portugal3232.23129.3750.23229
Romania779.66781841.31090
Slovak Republic2062.71862.31940.32370.2
Slovenia1372.8868.62437.4990.9
Spain3142.52449.73028.83048.5
Sweden1273.41763.61442.5595
Switzerland974.61166.5946.51389.1
Turkey1764.71265.42338.61972.8
United Kingdom2849.72449.71641.92953.3

Cost Recovery

The corporate income tax is intended to be a tax on profits, not revenues. Thus, it is important that a tax code properly defines what constitutes taxable incomeTaxable income is the amount of income subject to tax, after deductions and exemptions. For both individuals and corporations, taxable income differs from—and is less than—gross income. . If a tax code does not allow businesses to account for all the costs of doing business, it will inflate a business’ taxable income and thus its tax bill.

Loss Offset Rules: Carryforwards and Carrybacks

Loss carryover provisions allow businesses to either deduct current year losses against future profits (carryforwards) or deduct current year losses against past profits (carrybacks). Carryover provisions help businesses “smooth” their risk and income. Ideally, a tax code allows businesses to carry forward their losses for an unlimited number of years, ensuring that a business is taxed on its average profitability over time.

In 18 of the 32 ETPS countries, corporations can carry forward losses indefinitely in 2023, although 12 limit the amount of taxable income that can be offset by losses from previous years.[6] Of the 14 countries with time limits, the average loss carryforward period is six years. Hungary, Poland, and Slovakia have the most restrictive loss carryover provisions in the ETPS: carrybacks are not allowed, and carryforwards are not only limited to five years but also capped at 50 percent of taxable income (coded as 2.5 years).[7] The ETPS ranks countries that allow losses to be carried forward indefinitely without limits better than countries that impose time or deductibility restrictions on carryforwards.

Countries tend to be significantly more restrictive with loss carryback provisions than with carryforward provisions. In 2023, only the Estonian and Latvian systems allow, by design, unlimited carrybacks of losses.[8] Of the six countries that allow time-limited carrybacks, the average period is 1.25 years.[9] The ETPS penalizes the 24 countries that do not allow any loss carrybacks.

Capital Cost Recovery: Machines, Buildings, and Intangibles

Businesses determine their profits by subtracting costs from revenue. However, in most jurisdictions, capital investments are not treated like other regular costs that can be subtracted from revenue in the year the money is spent. Instead, businesses are required to write off these costs over several years or even decades, depending on the type of asset. DepreciationDepreciation is a measurement of the “useful life” of a business asset, such as machinery or a factory, to determine the multiyear period over which the cost of that asset can be deducted from taxable income. Instead of allowing businesses to deduct the cost of investments immediately (i.e., full expensing), depreciation requires deductions to be taken over time, reducing their value and discouraging investment. schedules specify the amounts businesses are legally allowed to write off, as well as the time period over which assets need to be written off.

The ETPS measures a country’s capital allowances for three asset types, machinery, industrial buildings, and intangibles.[10] Capital allowances are expressed as a percent of the present value cost that corporations can write off over the life of an asset. A 100 percent capital allowanceA capital allowance is the amount of capital investment costs, or money directed towards a company’s long-term growth, a business can deduct each year from its revenue via depreciation. These are also sometimes referred to as depreciation allowances. represents a business’ ability to deduct the full cost of an investment over its life in real terms. Countries that provide faster write-offs for capital investments receive better scores in the ETPS.

On average, across the ETPS, businesses can write off 86.5 percent of investment costs in machinery, 51.6 percent of the cost of industrial buildings, and 82.6 percent of the cost of intangibles, in real terms.

Inventories

Like capital investments, the costs of inventories are not written off in the year of purchase. Instead, the costs of inventories are deducted at sale. As a result, governments need to define the total cost of inventories sold. There are generally three methods used to calculate inventories: last in, first out (LIFO); average cost; and first in, first out (FIFO).

Countries that allow businesses to choose the LIFO method receive the best scores, those that allow the average cost method receive an average score, and countries that only allow the FIFO method receive the worst scores. Twelve ETPS countries allow companies to use the LIFO method of accounting, 13 countries use the average cost method of accounting, and seven countries limit companies to the FIFO method of accounting.[11]

Allowance for Corporate Equity

Businesses can finance their operations through debt or equity. Five ETPS countries—Belgium, Cyprus, Italy, Malta, Poland, Portugal, and Turkey—have introduced an allowance for corporate equity.[12] All countries except Malta and Poland apply the allowance only to new equity instead of all equity, limiting the tax revenue costs while preserving the efficiency gains. The Belgian policy will be abolished in 2024. The allowance rate is frequently based on the corporate or government bond rate and in some cases is adjusted by a risk premium.[13]

Countries that have implemented an allowance for corporate equity receive a better score in the ETPS.

Tax Incentives and Complexity

Good tax policy treats economic decisions neutrally by neither encouraging nor discouraging one activity over another. A tax incentive is a tax creditA tax credit is a provision that reduces a taxpayer’s final tax bill, dollar-for-dollar. A tax credit differs from deductions and exemptions, which reduce taxable income, rather than the taxpayer’s tax bill directly. , deduction, or preferential tax rate that exclusively applies for a specific type of economic activity and can thus distort economic decisions.

The ETPS considers whether countries provide incentives such as patent box provisions and research and development (R&D) tax subsidies. Countries that provide such incentives are scored worse than those that do not.

Patent Boxes

Due to an increasingly globalized and mobile economy, countries have searched for ways to prevent corporations from reincorporating or shifting operations or profits elsewhere. One response to the increase in capital mobility has been the creation of patent boxes.

Patent boxes—also referred to as intellectual property (IP) regimes—provide tax rates on income derived from IP that are below statutory corporate tax rates. Eligible types of IP are most commonly patents and software copyrights. Patent boxes are an income-based, rather than an expenditure-based, tax incentive limiting its benefits to successful R&D projects that have produced IP rights rather than decreasing the ex-ante risks of R&D through cost reductions.

Intellectual property is extremely mobile. Hence, a country can use the lower tax rate of a patent box to entice corporations to hold their intellectual property within its borders. Research suggests that patent boxes are likely to attract new income derived from patents, implying that businesses reduce their corporate tax liability by shifting IP-related income. Tax revenues, however, are likely to decline, as the negative revenue effects of the lower statutory rate on patent income can be only partially offset by revenues from newly attracted patent income.[14]

In recent years, patent box rules have become more stringent in some countries as the OECD requirements for countering harmful tax practices have been adopted. Countries that follow the OECD standards now require companies to have substantial R&D activity within their borders to benefit from tax preferences associated with their intellectual property.[15]

Instead of providing patent boxes for intellectual property, countries should recognize that all capital is mobile to some degree and lower their corporate tax rates across the board. This would encourage investment of all kinds, rather than merely incentivizing corporations to locate their patents in a specific country.

Sixteen ETPS countries—Belgium, Cyprus, France, Hungary, Ireland, Lithuania, Luxembourg, Malta, the Netherlands, Poland, Portugal, Slovakia, Spain, Switzerland, Turkey, and the United Kingdom—have patent box legislation, with rates and exemptions varying among countries.[16] Countries with patent box regimes receive a lower score.

Research and Development

In the absence of full expensingFull expensing allows businesses to immediately deduct the full cost of certain investments in new or improved technology, equipment, or buildings. It alleviates a bias in the tax code and incentivizes companies to invest more, which, in the long run, raises worker productivity, boosts wages, and creates more jobs. , expenditure-based R&D tax incentives (partially) offset the tax costs of business investment. Unfortunately, R&D tax incentives are rarely neutral—they usually define very specific activities that qualify—and are often complex in their implementation.

As with other incentives, R&D incentives distort investment decisions and lead to an inefficient allocation of resources.[17] Additionally, the desire to secure R&D incentives encourages lobbying activities that consume resources and detract from investment and production. In Italy, for instance, firms can engage in a negotiation process for incentives, such as easy term loans and tax credits.[18]

Countries could better use the revenue spent on special tax incentives to provide a lower business tax rate across the board or to improve the tax treatment of capital investment.

The implied tax subsidy rate on R&D expenditures, developed by the ETPS, measures the extent of expenditure-based R&D tax relief across countries. Implied tax subsidy rates are measured as the difference between one unit of investment in R&D and the pretax income required to break even on that investment unit, assuming a representative firm. In other words, it measures the extent of the preferential treatment of R&D in a given tax system. The more generous the tax provisions for R&D, the higher the implied tax subsidy rates for R&D. An implied subsidy rate of zero means R&D does not receive preferential tax treatment.

Among ETPS countries, Iceland has the highest implied tax subsidy rate on R&D expenditures, at 36 percent. Portugal and France provide the second and third most generous relief, with implied tax subsidy rates of 35 and 34.25 percent, respectively.

Of the countries that grant notable relief, Croatia (4.75 percent), Turkey (6 percent), and Denmark (6.5 percent) are the least generous. The implied tax subsidy rates of Bulgaria, Cyprus, Estonia, Finland, Latvia, Luxembourg, Malta, and Switzerland do not show any significant expenditure-based R&D tax relief.[19]

Countries that provide more generous expenditure-based R&D tax incentives receive a lower score on the ETPS.

Digital Services Taxes

Over the last few years, several ETPS countries have implemented so-called digital services taxes (DSTs). DSTs are taxes on selected gross revenue streams of large digital businesses. Their tax base typically includes revenues either derived from a specific set of digital goods or services (for example, targeted online advertising) or based on the number of digital users within a country. Relatively high domestic and global revenue thresholds limit the tax to large multinationals. As of 2023, eight ETPS countries have implemented a DST: Austria, France, Hungary, Italy, Poland, Spain, Turkey, and the United Kingdom.[20]

Countries that have implemented a DST receive a lower score on the ETPS.

Complexity

The ETPS quantifies corporate tax code complexity by measuring the number of separate taxes (and rates) that apply to business income and the existence of surtaxA surtax is an additional tax levied on top of an already existing business or individual tax and can have a flat or progressive rate structure. Surtaxes are typically enacted to fund a specific program or initiative, whereas revenue from broader-based taxes, like the individual income tax, typically cover a multitude of programs and services. rates on business income. These burdens are measured by tallying up the separate rates that apply to business income and identifying applicable surtaxes.

Four countries apply a surtax to all or part of their corporate income tax: France, Germany, Luxembourg, and Portugal. Eighteen countries apply an alternative minimum tax or multiple tax rates on corporate income.

Countries that have multiple rates that apply to corporate income and levy surtaxes on parts of corporate income taxes receive worse scores on the ETPS.

Individual Taxes

Individual income taxes are levied on an individual’s or household’s income to fund general government operations. These taxes are typically progressive, meaning that the rate at which an individual’s income is taxed increases as the individual earns more income.

In addition, countries have payroll taxes—also referred to as social security contributions or social insurance taxes. These typically flat-rate taxes are levied on wage income in addition to a country’s general individual income tax.

A country’s score for its individual income tax is determined by three subcategories: the rate and progressivity of wage taxation, income tax complexity, and the extent to which the income tax double taxes corporate income. Table 3 shows the ranks and scores for the entire individual taxes category as well as the rank and score for each subcategory.

Taxes on Ordinary Income

A country’s taxes on ordinary income are measured according to three variables: the top rate at which ordinary income is taxed, the top income tax threshold, and the economic efficiency of labor taxation.

Table 3. Individual Taxes

CountryOverall RankOverall ScoreReal Property Taxes RankReal Property Taxes ScoreWealth/Estate Taxes RankWealth/Estate Taxes ScoreCapital/Transaction Taxes RankCapital/Transaction Taxes Score
Belgium2547.3560.62848.22247.8
Bulgaria1064.4560.6869.4577.7
Croatia482.11100869.4577.7
Cyprus382.5110011002645.1
Czech Republic771.4560.6869.41100
Denmark1064.4560.6869.4577.7
Estonia1100110011001100
Finland1759.5560.6869.41962.5
France2547.3560.62848.22247.8
Germany1064.4560.6869.4577.7
Greece2154560.6869.42645.1
Hungary1954.8560.6869.42247.8
Iceland2941.92821.2869.41363
Ireland1759.5560.6869.41962.5
Italy3228.62821.22848.22844.7
Latvia675.2560.61100577.7
Lithuania771.4560.6869.41100
Luxembourg1459.7560.6869.41363
Malta288.1110011001962.5
Netherlands1459.7560.6869.41363
Norway1360.2560.62757.5577.7
Poland2449.1560.6869.43129.9
Portugal1459.7560.6869.41363
Romania2746.62821.2869.4577.7
Slovak Republic577.6560.61100485.2
Slovenia2746.62821.2869.4577.7
Spain3038.8560.63126.92844.7
Sweden970.5560.611001363
Switzerland3134.1560.63126.93129.9
Turkey2253.8560.6869.42844.7
United Kingdom1954.8560.6869.42247.8

Top Statutory Personal Income Tax Rate

Most countries’ income tax systems have a progressive taxA progressive tax is one where the average tax burden increases with income. High-income families pay a disproportionate share of the tax burden, while low- and middle-income taxpayers shoulder a relatively small tax burden. structure. This means that, as individuals earn more income, they move into tax brackets with higher tax rates. The top statutory personal income tax rate is the top tax rate on all income over a certain level.

Countries with high top statutory personal income tax rates receive a worse score on the ETPS than countries with lower top rates. Denmark has the highest top personal income tax rate, at 55.9 percent, followed by Austria at 55 percent. Bulgaria and Romania have the lowest, both at 10 percent.[21]

Income Level at Which Top Statutory Personal Income Tax Rate Applies

The level at which the top statutory personal income tax rate first applies is also important. Countries with top statutory personal income tax rates that apply at lower levels score better on the ETPS. The ETPS bases its measure on the income level at which the top rate first applies as compared to the country’s average income. According to this measure, Austria applies its top tax rate at the highest level of income (the top personal income tax rate applies at 20.3 times the average Austrian income), whereas Bulgaria and Hungary apply their top rates on the first euro, with flat personal income taxes of 10 and 15 percent, respectively.[22]

The Economic Cost of Labor Taxation

One way to examine the efficiency of labor taxation in a country is to control for the level of labor taxation using the marginal tax wedgeA tax wedge is the difference between total labor costs to the employer and the corresponding net take-home pay of the employee. It is also an economic term that refers to the economic inefficiency resulting from taxes. .[23] The marginal tax wedge influences the choice to earn another euro of income while the average tax wedge measures the tax burden at the current income level.[24] A higher ratio means that as one earns more income, the influence of the tax system on those decisions, and the related economic losses, grows. A lower ratio means that individuals can decide to work more without the tax system changing their decisions.

The ETPS gives countries with high ratios a worse score due to the larger impact that those systems have on workers’ decisions. Bulgaria and Hungary have the lowest ratio of 1, meaning the next euro earned faces the same tax burden as current earnings. This is because both countries have a flat income tax, so the average tax wedges are the same. In contrast, the highest ratios are found in Ireland (1.58) and France (1.55). The average across ETPS countries is 1.27.[25]

Complexity

Complexity is measured by the existence of any surtax on personal income. This measure indicates a non-standard approach to taxation of labor income and a less transparent personal income tax system. The ETPS penalizes countries with surtaxes.

Two ETPS countries levy a surtax on personal income: Germany and Luxembourg. Germany levies a 5.5 percent solidarity surcharge on income tax paid in excess of EUR 17,539, equivalent to labor income above EUR 65,500 for single filers, increasing its top marginal income tax rate from 45 percent to 47.475 percent. Luxembourg levies a solidarity tax at 7 percent of taxes for taxpayers earning less than EUR 150,000 and at 9 percent on taxes on personal income above that threshold.

Capital Gains and Dividends Taxes

Capital gains taxes and personal dividend taxes are forms of double taxationDouble taxation is when taxes are paid twice on the same dollar of income, regardless of whether that’s corporate or individual income. of corporate profits that contribute to the tax burden on capital. When a corporation makes a profit, it pays corporate income tax. It can then generally do one of two things. The corporation can retain the after-tax profits, which boost the value of the business and thus its stock price. Stockholders then sell the stock and realize a capital gain, which requires them to pay tax on that income. Alternatively, the corporation can distribute the after-tax profits to shareholders in the form of dividends. Stockholders who receive dividends then pay dividends tax on that income. Generally, higher dividends and capital gains taxes create a bias against saving and investment, reduce capital formation, and slow economic growth.[26]

In the ETPS, a country receives a better score for lower capital gains and dividends taxes.

Capital Gains TaxA capital gains tax is levied on the profit made from selling an asset and is often in addition to corporate income taxes, frequently resulting in double taxation. These taxes create a bias against saving, leading to a lower level of national income by encouraging present consumption over investment. Rates

Countries generally tax capital gains at a lower rate than ordinary income, provided that specific requirements are met. The ETPS gives countries with higher capital gains tax rates a worse score than those with lower rates.

Denmark has the highest capital gains tax rate in the ETPS at 42 percent. Belgium, Cyprus, the Czech Republic, Luxembourg, Slovakia, Slovenia, Switzerland, and Turkey do not tax long-term capital gains.[27]

Dividend Tax Rates

Dividend taxes can adversely impact capital formation in a country. Countries’ rates are expressed as the top marginal personal dividend tax rate after any imputation or credit system.

Countries with lower overall dividend tax rates score better on the ETPS due to the dividend tax rate’s effect on the cost of investment (i.e., the cost of capital) and the more neutral treatment between saving and consumption. Ireland has the highest dividend tax rate in the ETPS at 51 percent. Estonia and Latvia have dividend tax rates of 0 percent due to their cash-flow corporate tax systems. Malta imposes effective tax rates on dividends of 0 percent or below due to its dividend imputation system. The ETPS average is 21.7 percent.[28]

Consumption Taxes

Consumption taxes are levied on individuals’ purchases of goods and services. In the EU, the value-added tax is the most common general consumption tax.[29] Most general consumption taxes either do not tax intermediate business inputs or allow a credit for taxes already paid on them, which makes them one of the most economically efficient means of raising tax revenue.

A country’s consumption tax score is broken down into three subcategories: the tax rate, the tax base, and complexity. Table 4 displays the ranks and scores for the consumption taxes category.

Consumption Tax Rate

Ideally, a VAT should be levied at the standard rate on all final consumption. Countries with lower consumption tax rates score better than those with higher tax rates.

The average general consumption tax rate in the ETPS is 21.1 percent. Hungary has the highest tax rate at 27 percent while Switzerland has the lowest tax rate at 7.7 percent.[30]

Table 4. Consumption Taxes

CountryOverall RankOverall ScoreRate RankRate ScoreBase RankBase Score
Austria954.9845.91372.3
Belgium1347.61441.52165.4
Bulgaria660.9845.9583.8
Croatia2537.628241274.6
Cyprus366550.3386.7
Czech Republic1247.71441.52065.5
Denmark1744.12824287.1
Estonia860.7845.9783.5
Finland1843.82528.4879.3
France2241.8845.92947.2
Germany760.8550.31176.6
Greece3131.82528.42556.4
Hungary3225.53215.21965.5
Iceland2439.92528.41671.9
Ireland2833.72232.82752.8
Italy30322037.13042.4
Latvia1445.81441.52261.9
Lithuania1644.31441.52459
Luxembourg280.4259.11100
Malta465.2354.7978
Netherlands10541441.51077.8
Norway2142.42824683.8
Poland2933.42232.82852.3
Portugal1943.62232.81572
Romania2733.8550.33224.6
Slovak Republic1545.4845.92654
Slovenia2341.42037.12360.6
Spain11511441.51771.8
Sweden20432824485
Switzerland110011001871.7
Turkey562.2354.71472.1
United Kingdom2637.1845.93138

Consumption Tax Base

While a VAT should be levied on all final consumption, many countries’ consumption tax bases are far from this ideal. Many countries exempt certain goods and services from the VAT or tax them at a reduced rate.

VAT/Sales Tax ExemptionA tax exemption excludes certain income, revenue, or even taxpayers from tax altogether. For example, nonprofits that fulfill certain requirements are granted tax-exempt status by the Internal Revenue Service (IRS), preventing them from having to pay income tax. Threshold

Most ETPS countries set exemption thresholds for their VATs/sales taxes. If a business is below a certain annual revenue threshold, it is not required to participate in the VAT system.

Countries receive better scores for lower thresholds. Romania receives the worst threshold score with a VAT threshold of around EUR 165,000.[31] Spain and Turkey receive the best scores for having no general VAT/sales taxA sales tax is levied on retail sales of goods and services and, ideally, should apply to all final consumption with few exemptions. Many governments exempt goods like groceries; base broadening, such as including groceries, could keep rates lower. A sales tax should exempt business-to-business transactions which, when taxed, cause tax pyramiding. exemption threshold. The average across ETPS countries that have a VAT threshold is approximately EUR 54,700.[32]

Consumption Tax Base as a Percent of Total Consumption

One way to measure a country’s VAT base is the VAT revenue ratio. This ratio looks at the difference between the VAT revenue actually collected and collectable VAT revenue under a VAT that was applied at the standard rate on all final consumption. The difference in actual and potential VAT revenues is due to 1) policy choices to exempt certain goods and services from VAT or tax them at a reduced rate,[33] and 2) a lack of VAT compliance.[34] Countries with tax base ratios near 1—signifying a pure tax base—score better.

Under this measure, Bulgaria has the broadest tax base, covering 95.9 percent of total consumption. Luxembourg and Estonia follow with ratios of 0.86 and 0.78, respectively. Greece (0.36), Italy (0.44), and the United Kingdom (0.45) have the worst ratios. The ETPS average tax base ratio is 0.59.[35]

Property Taxes

Property taxes are government levies on the assets of an individual or business. The methods and intervals of collection vary widely among the types of property taxes. Estate and inheritance taxes, for example, are due upon the death of an individual and the passing of his or her estate to an heir. Taxes on real property, on the other hand, are paid at set intervals—often annually—on the value of taxable property such as land and real estate.

Table 5 shows the ranks and scores for the property taxes category and each of its subcategories, which are real property taxes, wealth and estate taxes, and capital and transaction taxes.

Real Property Taxes

Real property taxes are levied on a recurrent basis on taxable property. For example, in most German federal states, businesses and individuals pay a property tax to their municipality based on the value of their real property.

Structure of Property Taxes

Although taxes on real property are generally an efficient way to raise revenue, some real property taxes can become direct taxes on capital. This occurs when a tax applies to more than just the value of the land itself, such as the buildings or structures on the land. This increases the cost of capital, discourages the formation of capital (such as the building of structures), and can negatively impact business location decisions.

When a business wants to improve its property through renovations or expanding a factory, a property tax that applies to both the land and those improvements directly increases the costs of those improvements. However, a tax that just applies to the value of the land would not create an incentive against property improvements.

Countries that tax the value of structures and buildings as well as land receive the worst scores on the ETPS. Some countries mitigate this treatment with a deduction for property taxes paid against corporate taxable income. These countries receive slightly better scores. Countries receive the best possible score if they either have no property tax or only tax land.

Table 5. Property Taxes

CountryOverall RankOverall ScoreReal Property Taxes RankReal Property Taxes ScoreWealth/Estate Taxes RankWealth/Estate Taxes ScoreCapital/Transaction Taxes RankCapital/Transaction Taxes Score
Austria2352.82821.211001363
Belgium2547.3560.62848.22247.8
Bulgaria1064.4560.6869.4577.7
Croatia482.11100869.4577.7
Cyprus382.5110011002645.1
Czech Republic771.4560.6869.41100
Denmark1064.4560.6869.4577.7
Estonia1100110011001100
Finland1759.5560.6869.41962.5
France2547.3560.62848.22247.8
Germany1064.4560.6869.4577.7
Greece2154560.6869.42645.1
Hungary1954.8560.6869.42247.8
Iceland2941.92821.2869.41363
Ireland1759.5560.6869.41962.5
Italy3228.62821.22848.22844.7
Latvia675.2560.61100577.7
Lithuania771.4560.6869.41100
Luxembourg1459.7560.6869.41363
Malta288.1110011001962.5
Netherlands1459.7560.6869.41363
Norway1360.2560.62757.5577.7
Poland2449.1560.6869.43129.9
Portugal1459.7560.6869.41363
Romania2746.62821.2869.4577.7
Slovak Republic577.6560.61100485.2
Slovenia2746.62821.2869.4577.7
Spain3038.8560.63126.92844.7
Sweden970.5560.611001363
Switzerland3134.1560.63126.93129.9
Turkey2253.8560.6869.42844.7
United Kingdom1954.8560.6869.42247.8

Every ETPS country except Croatia, Cyprus, and Malta applies recurrent taxes to real property. Estonia is the only country with a property tax that is levied only on the value of land, which excludes the value of any buildings or structures on the land.[36] Of the 28 ETPS countries with taxes on all capital, 23 allow for a deduction against corporate taxable income.[37]

Wealth and Estate Taxes

Many countries also levy property taxes on an individual’s wealth. These taxes can take the form of estate or inheritance taxes that are levied either upon an individual’s estate at death or upon the assets transferred from the decedent’s estate to the heirs. These taxes can also take the form of a recurring tax on an individual’s wealth. Estate and inheritance taxes limit resources available for investment or production and reduce the incentive to save and invest.[38] This reduction in investment adversely affects economic growth. Moreover, these taxes, the estate and inheritance taxAn inheritance tax is levied upon an individual’s estate at death or upon the assets transferred from the decedent’s estate to their heirs. Unlike estate taxes, inheritance tax exemptions apply to the size of the gift rather than the size of the estate. especially, can be avoided with certain planning techniques, which makes the tax an inefficient and unnecessarily complex source of revenue.

Wealth Taxes

In addition to estate and inheritance taxes, some countries levy wealth taxes. Wealth taxes are often low-rate, progressive taxes on an individual’s or family’s assets or the assets of a corporation. Unlike estate taxes, wealth taxes are levied on an annual basis. While some countries levy a comprehensive tax on net wealth, others limit their wealth taxes to selected assets, such as security accounts, financial assets held abroad, or real estate.

Three countries levy net wealth taxes: Norway, Spain, and Switzerland. Belgium, France, and Italy impose wealth taxes on selected assets. Countries with no wealth tax receive the best score, countries with wealth taxes on selected assets receive an average score, and countries with net wealth taxes receive the lowest score.[39]

Estate, Inheritance, and Gift Taxes

Estate taxes are levied on the value of an individual’s taxable estate at the time of death and are paid by the estate itself, while inheritance taxes are levied on the value of assets transferred to an individual’s heirs upon death and are paid by the heirs (not the estate of the deceased individual). Gift taxes are taxes on the transfer of property (cash, stocks, and other property) that are typically used to prevent individuals from circumventing estate and inheritance taxes by gifting away their assets before death.

Rates, exemption levels, and rules vary substantially among countries. In Italy, for example, exemptions of up to EUR 1 million may apply for bequests to close relatives. Belgium’s Brussels capital region, on the other hand, has an inheritance tax with an exemption of EUR 15,000[40] and a variety of tax rates depending on who receives assets from the estate and what the assets are.[41]

Estate, inheritance, and gift taxes create significant compliance costs for taxpayers while raising insignificant amounts of revenue. According to OECD data for 2021, estate, inheritance, and gift taxes across the OECD raised an average of 0.15 percent of GDP in tax revenue, with the highest amount raised being only 0.74 percent of GDP in France, despite France’s top inheritance tax rate of up to 60 percent in some cases.[42]

Countries without these taxes score better than countries that have them. Eight countries in the ETPS have no estate, inheritance, or gift taxes: Austria, Cyprus, Estonia, Latvia, Malta, Norway, Slovakia, and Sweden. All others levy an estate, inheritance, or gift taxA gift tax is a tax on the transfer of property by a living individual, without payment or a valuable exchange in return. The donor, not the recipient of the gift, is typically liable for the tax. .[43]

Capital, Wealth, and Property Taxes on Businesses

There are various taxes countries levy on the assets and fixed capital of businesses. These include taxes on the transfer of real property, taxes on the net assets of businesses, taxes on raising capital, and taxes on financial transactions. These taxes contribute directly to the cost of capital for businesses and reduce the after-tax rate of return on investment.

Property Transfer Taxes

Property transfer taxes are taxes on the transfer of real property (real estate, land improvements, machinery) from one person or firm to another. A common example in the United Kingdom is the stamp duty land tax which is commonly levied on the value of homes that are purchased by individuals.[44] Property transfer taxes represent a direct tax on capital and increase the cost of purchasing property.

Countries receive a worse score if they have property transfer taxes. Four ETPS countries do not have property transfer taxes: the Czech Republic, Estonia, Lithuania, and Slovakia.[45] Croatia and Cyprus offer businesses the option to apply VAT to property transfers instead, allowing them to deduct construction and purchasing costs.

Corporate Asset Taxes

Similar to wealth taxes, asset taxes are levied on the wealth, or assets, of a business. For instance, Luxembourg levies a 0.5 percent tax on the worldwide net wealth of nontransparent Luxembourg-based companies every year.[46] Similarly, cantons in Switzerland levy taxes on the net assets of corporations, varying from 0.001 percent to 0.5 percent of corporate net assets.[47] Other countries levy these taxes exclusively on bank assets.

Fifteen ETPS countries have some type of corporate wealth or asset tax. Fourteen of these countries have bank taxes of some kind.[48]

Capital Duties

Capital duties are taxes on the issuance of shares of stock. Typically, countries either levy these taxes at very low rates or require a small, flat fee. For example, Switzerland requires resident companies to pay a 1 percent tax on the issuance of shares of stock.[49] These types of taxes increase the cost of capital, limit funds available for investment, and make it more difficult to form businesses.[50]

Countries with capital duties score worse than countries without them. Six countries in the ETPS levy some type of capital duty.[51]

Financial Transaction Taxes

A financial transaction tax is a levy on the sale or transfer of a financial asset. Financial transaction taxes take different forms in different countries. Finland levies a tax of 1.6 percent on the transfer of Finnish securities. On the other hand, Poland levies a 1 percent stamp duty on exchanges of property rights based on the transaction value. For transactions on a stock exchange, the tax is the responsibility of the buyer.[52]

Financial transaction taxes impose an additional layer of taxation on the purchase or sale of stocks. Markets run on efficiency, and capital needs to flow quickly to its most economically productive use. A financial transaction tax impedes this process.[53]

The ETPS ranks countries with financial transaction taxes worse than countries without them. Twelve countries in the ETPS have financial transaction taxes, including France and the United Kingdom, while 20 countries do not impose financial transaction taxes.[54]

Cross-Border Tax Rules

In an increasingly globalized economy, businesses often expand beyond the borders of their home countries to reach customers and build supply chains around the world. Countries have defined rules that determine how, or if, corporate income earned in foreign countries is taxed domestically. Cross-border tax rules comprise the systems and regulations that countries apply to those business activities.

Table 6 displays the overall rank and score for the cross-border tax rules category as well as the ranks and scores for the subcategories, including dividends and capital gains exemptions (territoriality), withholdingWithholding is the income an employer takes out of an employee’s paycheck and remits to the federal, state, and/or local government. It is calculated based on the amount of income earned, the taxpayer’s filing status, the number of allowances claimed, and any additional amount of the employee requests. taxes, tax treaties, and anti-tax avoidance rules.

Territoriality

Under a territorial tax system, multinational businesses pay taxes to the countries in which they earn their income. This means that territorial tax regimes do not generally tax corporate income earned in foreign countries. A worldwide tax systemA worldwide tax system for corporations, as opposed to a territorial tax system, includes foreign-earned income in the domestic tax base. As part of the 2017 Tax Cuts and Jobs Act (TCJA), the United States shifted from worldwide taxation towards territorial taxation. —such as the system previously employed by the United States—requires companies to pay taxes on worldwide income, regardless of where it is earned. Several countries—as is now the case in the U.S.—operate some sort of hybrid system. In the ETPS, Ireland is the only country that employs worldwide taxation of dividends, while Croatia and Poland levy worldwide taxes on capital gains.

Countries enact territorial tax systems through so-called “participation exemptions,” which include full or partial exemptions for foreign-earned dividend or capital gains income (or both). Participation exemptions eliminate the additional domestic tax on foreign income by allowing companies to ignore—some or all—foreign income when calculating their taxable income. A pure territorial system fully exempts foreign-sourced dividend and capital gains income.

Companies based in countries with worldwide tax systems are at a competitive disadvantage because they face potentially higher levels of taxation than their competitors based in countries with territorial tax systems. Additionally, taxes on repatriated corporate income in a company’s home country increase complexity and discourage investment and production.[55]

The territoriality of a tax system is measured by the degree to which a country exempts foreign-sourced income through dividend and capital gains exemptions.

Table 6. Cross-Border Tax Rules

CountryOverall RankOverall ScoreDiv/Cap Gains Exemption RankDiv/Cap Gains Exemption ScoreWithholding Taxes RankWithholding Taxes ScoreTax Treaties RankTax Treaties ScoreAnti-Tax Avoidance RankAnti-Tax Avoidance Score
Austria1568.411002160.51060.42236.7
Belgium2650.111003225.5666.23219.7
Bulgaria1073.11280.79792542366.1
Croatia3142.83044.61266.62343.92236.7
Cyprus2160.71280.7490.92637.22236.7
Czech Republic973.41280.71862.7865.2553.7
Denmark2749.31280.72745.42047.82236.7
Estonia1667.41280.7490.92734.3553.7
Finland1961.31280.71466.32047.81645.2
France875.52873.72257.9292.32236.7
Germany780.51195.61765.2567.1553.7
Greece2454.91280.71565.93028.5553.7
Hungary488.3110011001554.6553.7
Iceland3044.111002356.73217.82236.7
Ireland3238.33227.92646.52244.9553.7
Italy2258.22676.33038.64722236.7
Latvia1470.81280.711002734.3553.7
Lithuania2355.91280.71171.33126.5553.7
Luxembourg584.51100688.41455.5553.7
Malta1370.91280.711001849.72236.7
Netherlands388.61100688.4963.3553.7
Norway1171.92579.1880.71258.41645.2
Poland2948.43044.62451.11357.51645.2
Portugal2551.21280.73137.91948.81645.2
Romania2060.91280.71366.41554.62236.7
Slovak Republic28491280.72940.424431645.2
Slovenia1862.12959.11862.72931.4283
Spain17672676.32548.2666.2553.7
Sweden1271.411001076.81554.62236.7
Switzerland110011002845372.91100
Turkey682.711002062.21159.4366.1
United Kingdom295.711001665.811001645.2

Dividends Received Exemption

When a foreign subsidiary of a parent company earns income, it pays corporate income tax to the country in which it does business. After paying the tax, the subsidiary can either reinvest its profits into ongoing activities (by purchasing equipment or hiring more workers, for example) or it can distribute its profits back to the parent company in the form of dividends.

Under a worldwide tax system, the dividends received by a parent company are taxed again by the parent company’s home country, minus a tax credit for taxes already paid on that income. Under a pure territorial system, those dividends are exempt from taxation in the parent’s country.

Countries receive a score based on the level of dividend exemption they provide. Countries with no dividend exemption (worldwide tax systems) receive the worst score.

Twenty-six ETPS countries exempt all foreign-sourced dividends received by parent companies from domestic taxation. Six countries allow 95 percent or 97 percent of foreign-sourced dividends to be exempt from domestic taxation. Ireland is the only ETPS country that does not exempt foreign-sourced dividends regardless of their source country.[56]

Branch or Subsidiary Capital Gains Exclusion

Another feature of an international tax system is its treatment of capital gains earned through foreign investments. When a parent company invests in a foreign subsidiary (i.e., purchases shares in a foreign subsidiary), it can realize a capital gain on that investment if it later divests the asset. A territorial tax system would exempt these gains from domestic taxation, as they are derived from overseas activity.

Taxing foreign-sourced capital gains income at domestic tax rates can discourage saving and investment.

Countries that exempt foreign-sourced capital gains from domestic taxation receive a better score on the ETPS. Foreign-sourced capital gains are fully excluded from domestic taxation in 25 ETPS countries. Five countries partially exclude foreign-sourced capital gains. Poland and Croatia do not exclude foreign-sourced capital gains income from domestic taxation.[57]

Restrictions on Eligible Countries

An ideal territorial system would only concern itself with the profits earned within the home country’s borders. However, many countries have restrictions on their territorial systems that determine when a business’ dividends or capital gains received from foreign subsidiaries are exempt from domestic tax.

Some countries treat foreign corporate income differently depending on the country in which the foreign income was earned. For example, several countries restrict their territorial systems based on a “blacklist” of countries that do not follow certain requirements. Among EU countries, it is common to restrict the participation exemption to Member States of the European Economic Area.

The eligibility rules create additional complexity for companies and are often established in an arbitrary manner. Portugal, for instance, limits exemptions for foreign-sourced dividends and capital gains to those earned in countries that are not listed as a tax haven and that impose an income tax listed in the EU parent-subsidiary directive or have an income tax equal to at least 60 percent of the Portuguese corporate tax rate.[58] Italy, which normally allows a 95 percent tax exemption for foreign-sourced dividends paid to Italian shareholders, does not allow the exemption if the income was earned in a subsidiary located in a blacklisted country, unless evidence that an adequate level of taxation was borne by the foreign entity can be provided.[59]

In the ETPS, 21 of 32 countries that provide participation exemptions place restrictions on whether they exempt foreign-sourced income from domestic taxation based on the source country of the income.[60] Countries that have these restrictions on their territorial tax systems receive a worse score on the ETPS.

Withholding Taxes

When firms pay dividends, interest, and royalties to foreign investors or businesses, governments often require those firms to withhold a certain portion to pay as tax. For example, Switzerland requires businesses to withhold a maximum 35 percent tax on dividends and interest to foreign individuals unless a tax treaty provides otherwise.

These taxes make investment more costly both for investors, who will receive a lower return on dividends, and for firms, which must pay a higher amount in interest or royalty payments to compensate for the cost of the withholding taxes. These taxes also reduce funds available for investment and production and increase the cost of capital.

Countries with higher withholding tax rates on dividends, interest, and royalties score worse in the ETPS. Dividends, interest, and royalties from these countries do not always face the same tax rate as when distributed to domestic shareholders. Tax treaties between countries either reduce or eliminate withholding taxes.

Switzerland levies the highest dividend and interest withholding rates, requiring firms to withhold 35 percent of a dividend or interest payment paid to foreign entities or persons. Meanwhile, Cyprus, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, and Malta do not levy withholding taxes on dividends or interest payments.

For royalties, Belgium requires firms to retain the highest amount, at 30 percent, followed by France and Portugal, at 25 percent. Hungary, Latvia, Luxembourg, Malta, the Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, and Switzerland do not require companies to retain any amount of royalties for withholding tax purposes.[61]

Tax Treaty Network

Tax treaties align many tax laws between two countries and attempt to reduce double taxation, particularly by reducing or eliminating withholding taxes between the countries. Countries with a greater number of partners in their tax treaty network have more attractive tax regimes for foreign investment and receive a better score than countries with fewer treaties.

The United Kingdom has the broadest network of tax treaties (130 countries) and thus receives the best score. Iceland receives the worst score, with a treaty network of only 45 countries. Across the ETPS, the average size of a tax treaty network is 81 countries.[62]

Anti-Avoidance Rules

Anti-avoidance rules seek to prevent corporations from minimizing their tax liability through aggressive tax planning. These rules can take several forms, such as rules for controlled foreign corporations (CFCs), thin capitalization rules, and diverted profits taxes.

Anti-avoidance rules can make countries with uncompetitive tax structures even less competitive, as these rules can add significant complexity.[63]

Controlled Foreign Corporation Rules

CFC rules are intended to prevent corporations from shifting their pretax profits from a high-tax country to a low-tax country by using highly mobile forms of income. CFC rules are generally applied in multiple steps. First, they determine whether a foreign subsidiary is deemed a “controlled foreign corporation” for tax purposes. Second, if a foreign entity is deemed “controlled,” there is an applicability test to determine whether the CFC rules apply—generally through an income test, a predefined minimum tax rate, or a black/white list for countries. Third, if both tests are passed, the CFC rules subject the foreign corporation’s passive income (rent, royalties, interest), and sometimes active income, to the tax rate of the home country of the subsidiary’s parent corporation.

CFC rules vary widely among countries. The definition of what constitutes “control” is a somewhat arbitrary decision that often increases tax code complexity. For instance, Austria considers a subsidiary to be controlled if an Austrian company owns more than 50 percent of the shares or voting rights or is entitled to more than 50 percent of its profits, while Portugal considers a foreign company to be controlled if a Portuguese resident owns, directly or indirectly, at least 25 percent of its shares.

In 2016, an EU directive established that all EU Member States tax certain multinational, non-distributed income of CFCs if the parent company located in that Member State owns more than 50 percent of the shares of the CFC, and if the tax paid by the CFC is lower than the difference between the tax paid by the CFC if it had been situated in the Member State and the tax it actually paid.[64] All EU Member States have adopted CFC rules.[65]

Each country’s score in this subcomponent is based on four aspects of CFC rules: 1) whether there are CFC rules, 2) whether CFC rules apply to passive income or all income, 3) whether there are exemptions from the general CFC rules, and 4) whether the CFC rules have a strict minimum tax component. Countries receive the best score if they do not have CFC rules. Countries with CFC rules that have exemptions or only apply to passive income or income associated with non-genuine arrangements receive a better score. Countries score the worst if they have CFC rules that apply to all income and have no exemptions.

CFC rules exist in 31 of the 32 ETPS countries, with Switzerland being the only exception. In five of the 31 countries with CFC rules, the rules capture both active and passive income, while in 10 countries, the rules have a threshold for treating all income as passive income. In the remaining 16 countries with CFC rules, they only apply to passive income or income associated with non-genuine arrangements.[66]

Interest Deduction Limitations

Many countries limit the amount of interest expenses a multinational corporation, or one of its subsidiaries, can deduct for tax purposes. Low-tax countries create an incentive for companies to finance their investments with equity, while high-tax countries create an incentive for companies to finance investments with debt and use interest deductions to reduce their tax liabilities. To prevent businesses from lending money internally from entities in low-tax jurisdictions to entities in high-tax jurisdictions for tax purposes, most countries limit the amount companies can deduct in interest.

Interest deduction limitations can vary widely among countries, and there is much discretion available to governments in enforcing these laws.[67] Some countries limit interest deductions by applying transfer pricing regulations to interest rates. Others apply what are called “thin capitalization rules,” which limit the amount of deductible interest. The two most common types used in practice are “safe harbor rules” and “earnings stripping rules.” Safe harbor rules restrict the amount of debt for which interest is tax-deductible by defining a debt-to-equity ratio. Interest paid on debt exceeding this set ratio is not tax-deductible. Earnings stripping rules limit the tax-deductible share of debt interest to pretax earnings.

Interest deduction rules, particularly thin capitalization rules, have been shown to reduce the value of firms and distort firm decisions about how to invest in capital.[68] While interest deduction limitations can be seen as a way to address the debt bias inherent to most corporate tax systems, limiting the tax deductibility of interest expenses creates new distortions if interest income continues to be fully taxed.[69]

Countries that limit interest deductions with only transfer pricing regulations receive the best score. Countries with debt-to-equity ratios receive an average score, and countries with interest-to-pretax-earning limits receive the worst score.

Interest deduction limitations are found in all 32 countries measured in the ETPS. For instance, Turkey limits interest deductions if a firm’s debt-to-equity ratio reaches 3 to 1, while Belgium allows companies to deduct intra-group loans up to a 5 to 1 ratio. Germany and Spain limit interest deductions (regardless of whether they are for cross-border loans) to 30 percent of operating income.[70]

General Anti-Tax Avoidance Rules

Many countries apply general anti-tax avoidance rules to tax multinational companies with business structures designed specifically for tax advantages rather than economic reasons. These rules often follow the substance over form principle—emphasizing the economic purpose of a transaction rather than its legal or formal aspects—in determining how profits should be taxed.

The United Kingdom applies a diverted profits tax. A diverted profits tax is a set of complex rules and penalty rates that apply if a company is found to have minimized its tax burden through a structure without economic substance. The United Kingdom applies a 25 percent rate, though companies in certain industries can face higher rates.[71] These complex tax regimes result in high compliance costs for multinational companies as well as double taxation of some corporate profits.

Anti-abuse provisions of this nature are not currently accounted for in the ETPS. However, if they were appropriately accounted for, countries like the United Kingdom would likely receive worse scores on their cross-border tax rules—potentially also impacting their overall ranking.

Appendix

To access the full appendix, including tables, click the “Download Appendix” button at the top of the page.

Methodology

The ETPS is a relative ranking of the competitiveness and neutrality of the tax code in each of the 32 ETPS countries. It utilizes 39 variables across five categories: corporate income tax, individual taxes, consumption taxes, property taxes, and cross-border tax rules. Each category has multiple subcategories, and each subcategory can hold several of the 39 variables. For example, the consumption tax category contains two subcategories: rate and base. The consumption tax base subcategory then includes two variables: “VAT/sales tax threshold” and “VAT/sales tax base as a percent of total consumption.”

The ETPS is designed to measure a country’s tax code on a relative basis rather than on an absolute measurement. This means that a score of 100 does not signify the absolute best possible tax code but the best tax code among the 32 ETPS countries. Each country’s score on the ETPS represents its relative difference from the best country’s score.

The Calculation of the Variable, Subcategory, Category, and Final Score

First, the standard deviation and average of each variable is calculated. The standard deviation measures the average difference of a country’s tax variables from the mean among all 32 countries.[72] For example, the average corporate income tax rate across the 32 ETPS countries is about 21.2 percent, with a standard deviation of 5.8 percentage points. This means that on average, an ETPS country’s corporate tax rate is 5.8 percentage points off from the mean rate of 21.2 percent.

To compare variables with each other, it is necessary to standardize them, because each variable has a different mean and standard deviation. To standardize the variables, each observation is given a normalized score (z-score). This sets every variable’s mean to 0 with a standard deviation of 1. Each country’s score for each variable is a measure of its difference from the mean across all countries for that variable. A score of 0 means a country’s score is equal to the average, a score of -1 means it is one standard deviation below average, and a score of 1 is one standard deviation above average.

The score for the corporate tax rate demonstrates this process. As mentioned, the average corporate income tax rate among the 32 ETPS countries is 23.6 percent, and the standard deviation is 5.3 percentage points. Germany’s corporate tax rate normalized score is -1.5,[73] or 1.5 standard deviations less competitive than the average ETPS country. In contrast, Bulgaria’s tax rate of 10 percent is 1.9 standard deviations more competitive than the average ETPS country.

The next step is to combine variable scores to calculate subcategory scores. Within subcategories, each individual variable’s score is equally weighted and added together. For instance, the subcategory of cost recovery includes seven variables: loss carryback; loss carryforward; the present discounted value of depreciation schedules for machines, industrial buildings, and intangibles (each its own variable); inventory accounting method; and allowance for corporate equity. The scores for each of these seven variables are multiplied by 1/7, or 14.3 percent, to give them equal weight, and then added together. The result is the cost recovery subcategory score.

Calculating Subcategory Scores

From here, two transformations occur. First, to eliminate any negative values, the lowest z-score is multiplied by minus one. Then one is added to that value. For example, Malta has the worst z-score for the corporate income tax rate subcategory (-2.38). Thus, -2.376 multiplied by negative one is 2.376. Adding one to that product gives 3.376. Then 3.38 is added to each country’s z-score, giving the adjusted z-score. This sets the worst score in each subcategory to 1. For Malta, -2.38 plus 3.38 equals 1.

Second, the adjusted subcategory scores for each country are scaled to 100, relative to the country with the best score in each subcategory. This is done by taking each country’s adjusted z-score and dividing it by the best adjusted z-score in each category. For example, Hungary, which has the lowest corporate tax rate, has the best adjusted corporate rate subcategory z-score of 2.09, and receives a final subcategory score of 100.

Calculating Category Scores

The same method is used to create the category scores. First, the z-score for subcategories is averaged to create the initial category score. Then, the worst z-score is multiplied by minus one and one is added to that product. That resulting amount is added to each country’s z-score. For example, Portugal has the worst initial corporate category score of -1.08. Thus, -1.08 multiplied by negative one is 1.08. Adding one to that product gives 2.08. Then 2.08 is added to each country’s initial category score to give the adjusted initial category score. This sets the worst score in each category to 1. For Portugal, -1.08 plus 2.08 equals 1.

Second, the adjusted initial category scores for each country are scaled to 100, relative to the country with the best score in each category. This is done by taking each country’s adjusted initial category score and dividing it by the best adjusted initial category score in each category. For example, Latvia, which has the best corporate category score, has the best adjusted category score of 1.03, and receives a final category score of 100.

Calculating Final Scores

The same method is used to create the final score. First, the initial category scores are averaged to create the initial final score. Then, the lowest value of the initial final score is multiplied by negative one and one is added to that product. That resulting amount is added to each country’s initial final score. For example, France has the worst initial final score of -0.53. Thus, -0.53 multiplied by negative one is 0.53. Adding one to that product gives 1.53. Then 1.53 is added to each country’s initial final score (the adjusted initial final score). This sets the worst score in each category to 1.

Second, the adjusted initial final scores for each country are scaled to 100, relative to the country with the best score in each category. This is done by taking each country’s adjusted initial final score and dividing it by the best adjusted initial final score in each category. For example, Estonia, which has the best final score, has the best adjusted final score of 1.71, and receives a final category score of 100.

2023 European Tax Policy Scorecard components and methodology

Distribution of the Final Scores

Many of the countries shown in the ETPS have final scores that are grouped closely together. Though the scores range from 100 (Estonia) to 44.8 (France), there are 10 countries with scores in the 70s and 12 countries with scores in the 60s. The closeness of some of the scores means that small differences in variable values (such as a percentage-point difference in the corporate income tax rate or size of the VAT base) can mean the difference of several rank positions.

The distribution of the scores also shows the distance between first and second place, again demonstrating how significantly different the Estonian tax system is, even relative to the ETPS country with the second most competitive and neutral tax system, Bulgaria (with a final score of 92).

2023 European Tax Policy Scorecard methodology

Data Sources

The ETPS includes data from numerous sources, including:

  • Bloomberg Tax Country Guides
  • Deloitte International Tax Source
  • Ernst & Young International Tax Guides
  • European Commission: Christoph Spengel, Frank Schmidt, Jost Heckemeyer, and Katharina Nicolay, “Effective Tax Levels Using the Devereux/Griffith Methodology.”
  • Eurostat
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF)
  • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD)
  • Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation Database
  • PwC Worldwide Tax Summaries

The ETPS uses the most up-to-date data available as of July 2023. Data may not reflect changes in countries making rapid reforms. See footnotes for specific data citations. A detailed source documentation can be found at www.github.com/TaxFoundation/international-tax-competitiveness-index.


References

[1] Sean Bray, Daniel Bunn, and Joost Haddinga, “The Role of Pro-Growth Tax Policy and Private Investment in the European Union’s Green Transition,” Tax Foundation, May 4, 2023, https://taxfoundation.org/research/all/global/eu-green-transition-tax-policy/.

[2] The tax provisions chapter (Articles 110-113 TFEU) relates to the harmonization of legislation concerning turnover taxes, excise duties, and other forms of indirect taxation; the chapter on the approximation of laws (Articles 114-118 TFEU) covers taxes that have an indirect effect on the establishment of the internal market, with fiscal provisions not subject to the ordinary legislative procedure; other provisions relevant to tax policy, referring to the free movement of persons, services, and capital (Articles 45-66 TFEU), the environment (Articles 191-192 TFEU) and competition (Articles 107-109 TFEU).

[3] Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), “Tax and Economic Growth,” Economics Department Working Paper No. 620, Jul. 11, 2008.

[4] Malta’s integrated corporate tax rate is lower than its statutory rate, since its full imputation system avoids the double taxation of dividends.

[5] OECD, “OECD Tax Database, Table II.1 – Statutory corporate income tax rate,” updated April 2023, https://stats.oecd.org/index.aspx?DataSetCode=Table_II1; PwC, “Worldwide Tax Summaries: Corporate – Taxes on Corporate Income.”

[6] Countries with unlimited carryforwards are coded as having periods of 100 years. Some countries restrict the amount of taxable income that can be offset by losses each year. For example, Slovenia allows for indefinite carryforwards but only 63 percent of taxable income can be offset by losses in any given year. These restrictions are coded as the percentage of taxable income that can be offset by losses times the number of allowable years. Thus, Slovenia is coded as 63.

[7] Bloomberg Tax, “Country Guides,” https://bloomberglaw.com/product/tax/toc/source/511920/147664382; PwC, “Worldwide Tax Summaries,” https://pwc.com/gx/en/services/tax/worldwide-tax-summaries.html; and individual government websites.

[8] Estonia and Latvia do not have explicit loss carryover provisions. However, their cash-flow corporate tax system implicitly allows for unlimited loss carryforwards and carrybacks.

[9] Bloomberg Tax, “Country Guides;” PwC, “Worldwide Tax Summaries”; and individual government websites.

[10] Intangible assets are typically amortized, but the write-off is similar to depreciation.

[11] Christoph Spengel, Frank Schmidt, Jost Heckemeyer, and Katharina Nicolay, “Effective Tax Levels Using the Devereux/Griffith Methodology.” European Commission, October 2021, https://taxation-customs.ec.europa.eu/system/files/2022-03/final_report_2021_effective_tax_levels_revised_en.pdf; PwC, “Worldwide Tax Summaries: Corporate – Income Determination,” https://taxsummaries.pwc.com/australia/corporate/income-determination; and EY, “Worldwide Corporate Tax Guide 2022.”

[12] The European Commission also included an allowance for corporate equity in its proposal for a common corporate tax base in the European Union. See European Commission, “Common Consolidated Corporate Tax Base (CCCTB),” https://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/business/company-tax/common-consolidated-corporate-tax-base-ccctb_en. Switzerland has an optional allowance for corporate equity at the cantonal level, which is currently only in effect in the canton of Zurich. See PwC, “Worldwide Tax Summaries: Corporate – Deductions,” https://taxsummaries.pwc.com/switzerland/corporate/deductions.

[13] Bloomberg Tax, “Country Guides”; PwC, “Worldwide Tax Summaries: Corporate – Deductions”; and Spengel, Schmidt, Heckemeyer, and Nicolay, “Effective Tax Levels Using the Devereux/Griffith Methodology.”

[14] Rachel Griffith, Helen Miller, and Martin O’Connell, “Ownership of Intellectual Property and Corporate Taxation,” Journal of Public Economics 112 (April 2014): 12–23, https://sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0047272714000103.

[15] OECD, “Action 5: Agreement on Modified Nexus Approach for IP Regimes,” 2015, https://oecd.org/ctp/beps-action-5-agreement-on-modified-nexus-approach-for-ip-regimes.pdf; and OECD, “Harmful Tax Practices – Peer Review Results,” January 2022, http://oecd.org/tax/beps/harmful-tax-practices-peer-review-results-on-preferential-regimes.pdf.

[16] Bloomberg Tax, “Country Guides”; PwC, “Worldwide Tax Summaries: Corporate – Tax credits and incentives,” https://taxsummaries.pwc.com/australia/corporate/tax-credits-and-incentives; and OECD, “Intellectual Property Regimes,” https://qdd.oecd.org/data/IP_Regimes.

[17] This does not imply that R&D credits do not meet their policy goal of fostering innovation through R&D activity, technology transfer, and entrepreneurship. See IMF, “Acting Now, Acting Together,” April 2016, https://imf.org/en/Publications/FM/Issues/2016/12/31/Acting-Now-Acting-Together. However, R&D credits benefit certain firms and industries more than others, creating distortions in the economy. See Gary Guenther, “Research Tax Credit: Current Law and Policy Issues for the 114th Congress,” Congressional Research Service, Mar. 13, 2015, https://fas.org/sgp/crs/misc/RL31181.pdf, and Fulvio Castellacci and Christine Mee Lie, “Do the effects of R&D tax credits vary across industries? A meta-regression analysis,” Research Policy 44:4 (May 2015), 819-832, https://sciencedirect.com/science/article/abs/pii/S0048733315000128.

[18] Deloitte, “International Tax– Italy Highlights 2023,” January 2023, https://www2.deloitte.com/content/dam/Deloitte/global/Documents/Tax/dttl-tax-italyhighlights-2023.pdf.

[19] OECD, “R&D Tax Incentive Indicators: Implied tax subsidy rates on R&D expenditures,” https://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DataSetCode=RDSUB. The measure used in the ETPS is the average implied tax subsidy rate of loss-making and profitable SMEs and large firms.

[20] KPMG, “Taxation of the digitalized economy: Developments summary,” updated Jun. 27, 2022, https://tax.kpmg.us/content/dam/tax/en/pdfs/2022/digitalized-economy-taxation-developments-summary.pdf.

[21] Ibid.

[22] Ibid.

[23] The marginal tax burden faced by an average worker in a country and the total tax cost of labor for an average worker in a country are called the marginal and average tax wedges, respectively. The tax wedge includes income taxes and social security contributions (both the employee-side and the employer-side). The ratio of marginal to average tax wedges is calculated using the EC data of average total tax wedges over six intervals of income for single individuals without dependents and calculating the marginal tax wedges across five intervals. It is the average of marginal to average total tax wedges over the intervals between 50 percent, 67 percent, 80 percent, 100 percent, 125 percent, and 167 percent of average earnings.

[24] Cristina Enache, “A Comparison of the Tax Burden on Labor in the OECD,” Tax Foundation, Apr. 19, 2021, https://taxfoundation.org/publications/comparison-tax-burden-labor-oecd/.

[25] European Commission, “Economic and Financial Affairs, Economic databases and indicators, Tax and Benefit Indicators, Tax Wedge,” updated March 2023, https://europa.eu/economy_finance/db_indicators/tab/;.

[26] Daniel Bunn and Elke Asen, “Savings and Investment: The Tax Treatment of Stock and Retirement Accounts in the OECD,” Tax Foundation, May 26, 2021, https://taxfoundation.org/savings-and-investment-oecd/.

[27] Bloomberg Tax, “Country Guide”; PwC, “Quick Charts: Capital gains tax (CGT) rates,” https://taxsummaries.pwc.com/quick-charts/capital-gains-tax-cgt-rates; and PwC, “Worldwide Tax Summaries: Individual – Income determination,” https://taxsummaries.pwc.com/. When the capital gains tax rate varies by type of asset sold, the tax rate applying to the sale of listed shares after an extended period of time is used. Includes surtaxes if applicable.

[28] Bloomberg Tax, “Country Guides”; OECD, “OECD Tax Database, Table II.4 – Overall statutory tax rates on dividend income,” updated April 2023, https://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DataSetCode=TABLE_II4.

[29] There are other types of consumption taxes, such as excise taxes. However, these are generally narrowly based, as they are levied on specific goods, services, and activities, rather than all final consumption. The ETPS only considers general consumption taxes (VAT and retail sales tax).

[30] OECD, “Taxes on Consumption: Value Added Tax/Goods and Services Tax (VAT/GST) (1976-2021): VAT/GST: standard and any reduced rates (2022),” http://oecd.org/tax/tax-policy/tax-database/.

[31] Original measurements in U.S. dollars (purchasing power parity, PPP).

[32] OECD, “Taxes on Consumption: Value Added Tax/Goods and Services Tax (VAT/GST) (1976-2019): VAT/GST: Registration/Collection Thresholds (2021).”

[33] Cristina Enache, “Actionable VAT Policy Gap in Europe,” Tax Foundation, Jan. 17, 2023, https://taxfoundation.org/data/all/eu/vat-policy-gap-vat-revenue-efficiency/.

[34] The same concept can be applied to retail sales taxes.

[35] The VAT revenue ratio (VRR) was calculated using the following formula in line with the OECD’s VRR calculations: VRR = VAT Revenue/[(Consumption – VAT revenue) x standard VAT rate]. The calculations are based on OECD, “Consumption Tax Trends 2018,” Dec. 5, 2018, https://read.oecd-ilibrary.org/taxation/consumption-tax-trends-2018_ctt-2018-en#page92; For non-OECD countries, see Eurostat, “National Tax Lists – individual taxes,” updated Jul. 21, 2023, https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statistics-explained/index.php?title=Tax_revenue_statistics.

[36] When the property tax base is set at the subnational level, the ETPS evaluates the most representative model. For example, in Germany, some states tie property taxes only to the area, location, or value of the land. However, most states use the federal model which also taxes the value of buildings. German federal and state financial administrations, accessed Oct. 10, 2023, https://grundsteuerreform.de/.

[37] Deloitte, “Tax Guides and Highlights,” https://dits.deloitte.com/#TaxGuides; Bloomberg Tax, “Country Guides”; and PwC, “Worldwide Tax Summaries: Corporate – Income Determination.”

[38] Jared Walczak, “State Inheritance and Estate Taxes: Rates, Economic Implications, and the Return of Interstate Competition,” Tax Foundation, Jul. 17, 2017, https://taxfoundation.org/state-inheritance-estate-taxes-economic-implications/#_ftn84.

[39] Bloomberg Tax, “Country Guides”; and EY, “Worldwide Estate and Inheritance Tax Guide 2022,” https://ey.com/en_gl/tax-guides/worldwide-estate-and-inheritance-tax-guide.

[40] The average 2022 EUR-USD exchange rate was used. See IRS, “Yearly Average Currency Exchange Rates.”

[41] EY, “Worldwide Estate and Inheritance Tax Guide 2022.”

[42] OECD, “OECD Revenue Statistics – OECD Countries: Comparative tables.”

[43] Bloomberg Tax, “Country Guides”; EY, “Worldwide Estate and Inheritance Tax Guide 2022”; PwC, “Worldwide Tax Summaries: Individual Taxes – Other taxes.”

[44] UK Government, “Stamp Duty Land Tax – Overview,” https://gov.uk/stamp-duty-land-tax.

[45] Deloitte, “Tax Guides and Highlights”; Bloomberg Tax, “Country Guides.”

[46] Luxembourg levies this tax on non-Luxembourg companies as well, but only on wealth held within Luxembourg. See Government of the Grand Duchy of Luxembourg, “Net wealth tax,” Mar. 22, 2017, http://guichet.public.lu/entreprises/en/fiscalite/impots-benefices/impots-divers/impot-fortune/index.html.

[47] PwC, “Worldwide Tax Summaries: Corporate Taxes – Other taxes.”

[48] Bloomberg Tax, “Country Guides – Other Taxes,” and “Country Guides – Special Industries,” https://bloomberglaw.com/product/tax/toc_view_menu/3380.

[49] PwC, “Worldwide Tax Summaries: Corporate Taxes.”

[50] EUR-Lex, “Council Directive 2008/7/EC, concerning indirect taxes on the raising of capital,” February 2008, http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/ALL/?uri=CELEX:32008L0007.

[51] Bloomberg Tax, “Country Guides”; and PwC, “Worldwide Tax Summaries: Corporate Taxes.”

[52] Ibid.

[53] Colin Miller and Anna Tyger, “The Impact of a Financial Transaction Tax.”

[54] Ibid.

[55] Kyle Pomerleau, Daniel Bunn, and Thomas Locher, “Anti-Base Erosion Provisions and Territorial Tax Systems in OECD Countries,” Tax Foundation, Jul. 7, 2021, https://taxfoundation.org/anti-base-erosion-territorial-tax-systems.

[56] Deloitte, “Tax Guides and Highlights 2023”; Bloomberg Tax, “Country Guide”; EY, “Worldwide Corporate Tax Guide 2022”; and PwC, “Worldwide Tax Summaries.”

[57] Ibid.

[58] Deloitte, “Tax Guides and Highlights – Portugal Highlights 2023,” https://deloitte.com/content/dam/Deloitte/global/Documents/Tax/dttl-tax-portugalhighlights-2023.pdf.

[59] Deloitte, “Tax Guides and Highlights – Italy Highlights 2023,” https://deloitte.com/content/dam/Deloitte/global/Documents/Tax/dttl-tax-italyhighlights-2023.pdf.

[60] Deloitte, “Tax Guides and Highlights 2023”; Bloomberg Tax, “Country Guide”; EY, “Worldwide Corporate Tax Guide 2022”; and PwC, “Worldwide Tax Summaries.”

[61] Deloitte, “Domestic rates: Withholding tax,” https://dits.deloitte.com/#DomesticRatesSubMenu.

[62] EY, “Worldwide Corporate Tax Guide: 2022.” The source may not include all active tax treaties, potentially underestimating the scope of tax treaty networks. Tax treaties with former countries, such as the USSR, Yugoslavia, and Czechoslovakia, are not counted as one. Every country the treaty applies to is counted individually.

[63] Thomas Hoppe, Deborah Schanz, Susann Sturm, and Caren Sureth-Sloane, “The Tax Complexity Index – A Survey-Based Country Measure of Tax Code and Framework Complexity,” TRR 266 Accounting for Transparency Working Paper Series No. 5, WU International Taxation Research Paper Series No. 2019-06, Sep. 16, 2020, https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3469663.

[64] European Commission, “The Anti Tax Avoidance Directive,” Jan. 28, 2016, https://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/anti-tax-avoidance-directive_en.

[65] Sebastian Dueñas and Daniel Bunn, “Tax Avoidance Rules Increase the Compliance Burden in EU Member Countries,” Tax Foundation, Mar. 28, 2019, https://taxfoundation.org/eu-tax-avoidance-rules-increase-tax-compliance-burden/.

[66] Bloomberg Tax, “Country Guides: Anti-Avoidance Provisions – Controlled Foreign Company (CFC) Rules,” https://bloomberglaw.com/product/tax/bbna/chart/3/10077/347a743114754ceca09f7ec4b7015426; and PwC, “Worldwide Tax Summaries: Corporate – Group taxation,” https://taxsummaries.pwc.com/australia/corporate/group-taxation.

[67] Jennifer Blouin, Harry Huizinga, Luc Laeven, and Gaëtan Nicodème, “Thin Capitalization Rules and Multinational Firm Capital Structure,” International Monetary Fund Working Paper WP/14/12, January 2014, https://imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2014/wp1412.pdf.

[68] Ibid.

[69] For more details, see “Allowance for Corporate Equity” in the ETPS section “Corporate Income Tax.”

[70] Bloomberg Tax, “Country Guides: Anti-Avoidance Provisions – Thin Capitalization/Other Interest Deductibility Rules,” https://bloomberglaw.com/product/tax/bbna/chart/3/10077/a8a08d05c9450b676b4d835dbb64348c; and PwC, “Worldwide Tax Summaries: Corporate – Group taxation.”

[71] Kyle Pomerleau, Daniel Bunn, and Thomas Locher, “Anti-Base Erosion Provisions and Territorial Tax Systems in OECD Countries.”

[72] To calculate the standard deviation, we find the mean of a variable (corporate tax rates, for example) and the difference of each country’s tax rate from the mean tax rate among the 38 countries. We then take each country’s difference from the mean and find the average difference for the group.

[73] The true normal score is 1.5. The score is a negative value to reflect the fact that being higher than the OECD average is less ideal.

Share