Skip to content

Corporate Integration: An Important Component of Tax Reform

23 min readBy: Scott Greenberg

Key Findings

  • The combined top federal taxA tax is a mandatory payment or charge collected by local, state, and national governments from individuals or businesses to cover the costs of general government services, goods, and activities. rate on equity-financed corporate income in the United States is 50.47 percent, compared to a top federal tax rate of 43.4 percent on other business income.
  • Equity-financed corporate income is subject to a higher tax rate than other business income because it is subject to a double tax: once on the corporate level, through the corporate income taxA corporate income tax (CIT) is levied by federal and state governments on business profits. Many companies are not subject to the CIT because they are taxed as pass-through businesses, with income reportable under the individual income tax. , and once on the shareholder level, though the individual income taxAn individual income tax (or personal income tax) is levied on the wages, salaries, investments, or other forms of income an individual or household earns. The U.S. imposes a progressive income tax where rates increase with income. The Federal Income Tax was established in 1913 with the ratification of the 16th Amendment. Though barely 100 years old, individual income taxes are the largest source of tax revenue in the U.S. on dividends.
  • Taxing equity-financed corporate income at a higher rate encourages the misallocation of investment capital. Ideally, all business income would be subject to the same top tax rate, regardless of the legal form of the business or the method of financing.
  • Short of reforming the entire U.S. tax code, integrating the corporate and individual income taxes could eliminate the double taxationDouble taxation is when taxes are paid twice on the same dollar of income, regardless of whether that’s corporate or individual income. of corporate income.
  • There are several ways to integrate the corporate and individual tax codes, including allowing shareholders a credit for corporate taxes paid (credit imputation) or allowing corporations to deduct dividends paid (dividends paid deduction). Each of these strategies for corporate integration presents different opportunities and challenges.
  • Corporate integration would accomplish many of the same goals as a corporate rate cut, such as making the U.S. business climate more competitive. It could also end several economic distortions created by the current tax code, including the tax preference for debt financing over equity financing.

Introduction

According to recent reports, Congressional lawmakers are in the process of drafting a plan to integrate the individual and corporate tax codes.[1] Because Congress has not focused on the topic of corporate integration since 2003, many Americans may not be familiar with the idea of integrating the individual and corporate tax codes or the rationale for doing so.[2]

Under the current U.S. tax code, the taxation of business income varies based on the legal form of the business and the method of financing. Most importantly, income that is earned by corporations and funded by equity (stocks) is subject to a double tax: once on the corporate level, when it is earned, and once on the shareholder level, when it is distributed as dividends.[3]

The double taxation of equity-financed corporate income leads to several major economic distortions. It encourages investors to shift their investments from corporate to non-corporate businesses, leading to a less efficient allocation of capital. Furthermore, it incentivizes corporationAn S corporation is a business entity which elects to pass business income and losses through to its shareholders. The shareholders are then responsible for paying individual income taxes on this income. Unlike subchapter C corporations, an S corporation (S corp) is not subject to the corporate income tax (CIT). s to fund their operations with debt, rather than equity, leading to excessive leverage.

Corporate integration refers to a set of proposals to standardize the taxation of business income across legal forms and methods of financing. The chief advantage of corporate integration is that it would end the double taxation of equity-financed corporate income without eliminating the corporate income tax altogether.

It is a testament to the glacial pace of tax policy change in the United States that Congress has not yet enacted corporate integration.[4] Since 1975, there have been no fewer than twelve major corporate integration proposals from members of both parties in the legislative and executive branches.[5] However, none of these proposals have been passed.

Now that corporate integration is back on Congress’s agenda, this paper makes the case for why corporate integration is an important component of tax reform. It also outlines two ways to integrate the individual and corporate tax codes and discusses the opportunities and challenges presented by each.

The Double Taxation of Corporate Income

It is often useful to begin abstract discussions of tax policy with a concrete example. To introduce the topic of corporate integration, we can imagine a household with extra cash on hand, evaluating three investment options:

  1. It could invest in a partnership.
  2. It could invest in a corporate bond.
  3. It could invest in corporate stock.

Each of these investments is treated differently by the U.S. tax code. Most significantly, under the current federal tax code, investments in corporate stock are subject to a higher top combined federal tax rate than other investments:

Table 1. Top Combined Federal Tax Rate on Selected Financial Investments, 2016

Investing in a Partnership

Buying Corporate Bonds (Debt)

Buying Corporate Stocks (Equity)

43.4% 43.4% 50.47%

Notes: The tax rates shown above are marginal rates and apply to a marginal business investment.

To understand why this is the case, we can walk through how the federal tax code treats each of the investment types listed above:

  1. Income earned by a partnership is not subject to any business-level tax. Instead, the earnings are “passed through” to the owners of the partnership, who each pay individual income taxes on the earnings. As a result, partnership income is subject to a top tax rate of 43.4 percent (the top bracket of 39.6 percent, plus the 3.8 percent net investment income tax.)
  2. When a corporation earns income that is financed by debt, it is required to report the income under the corporate income tax. However, the corporation is also able to deduct its interest payments on its debt. This means that, on the margin, debt-financed corporate income is effectively excluded from the corporate income tax.[6] However, this income is subject to the individual income tax, once it is distributed to debt-holders in the form of interest. Individuals that hold corporate debt are taxed on the interest income at a top rate of 43.4 percent (the top bracket of 39.6 percent, plus the 3.8 percent net investment income tax).
  3. When a corporation earns income that is financed by equity, it is not allowed to deduct its dividend payments to shareholders, and the income is taxed at a top rate of 35 percent under the corporate income tax. The income is then subject to a second layer of taxes when it is distributed to shareholders as dividends, which are taxed at a top rate of 23.8 percent under the individual income tax. When taking both corporate and individual income taxes into account, equity-financed corporate income is subject to a top tax rate of 50.47 percent.

As these examples show, the U.S. tax code treats corporations differently than other forms of business. Specifically, corporate income is subject to two levels of taxation: once at the entity level, through the corporate income tax, and once at the individual level, through the individual income tax. On the other hand, income earned by pass-through businessA pass-through business is a sole proprietorship, partnership, or S corporation that is not subject to the corporate income tax; instead, this business reports its income on the individual income tax returns of the owners and is taxed at individual income tax rates. es, such as partnerships, is not subject to any entity-level taxes, and is only taxed through the individual income tax.

Furthermore, the federal tax burden on corporate income depends critically on the method of financing used by a corporation. For instance, if a corporation finances its activities exclusively with debt (such as by issuing bonds), its income is subject to a top tax rate of 43.4 percent, the same as the tax rate on pass-through businesses:

Table 2. The Combined Federal Corporate Tax Rate on Debt-Financed Income

Corporate Income Tax

Individual Income Tax

Corporate profits

$100.00

Interest paid deduction

-$100.00

Interest received

$100.00

Corporate taxable income

$0.00

Individual income tax owed (43.4 percent rate)

$43.40

Corporate income tax owed

$0.00

After-tax income

$56.60

In the example shown above, a corporation makes $100 in profits and pays out $100 in interest on the debt used to finance its activities. Because the corporation is able to deduct its interest payments from its income, it owes no corporate income tax. However, the individuals that receive the $100 in interest payments pay a top individual income tax rate of 43.4 percent, leaving them with $56.60 in after-tax incomeAfter-tax income is the net amount of income available to invest, save, or consume after federal, state, and withholding taxes have been applied—your disposable income. Companies and, to a lesser extent, individuals, make economic decisions in light of how they can best maximize their earnings. .

On the other hand, if a corporation finances its activities exclusively with equity (such as by issuing stock), its income is subject to a top tax rate of 50.47 percent, significantly higher than the tax rate on other business income:

Table 3. The Combined Federal Corporate Tax Rate on Equity-Financed Income

Corporate Income Tax

Individual Income Tax

Corporate profits

$100.00

Corporate income tax owed

(35 percent rate)

$35.00

Dividends distributed

$65.00

Dividends received

$65.00

Individual income tax owed (23.8 percent rate)

$15.47

After-tax income

$49.53

While the corporation in this example also makes $100 in profits, it is subject to a different tax burden because of its method of financing. Unlike interest payments, dividends that corporations pay to shareholders are not deductible. As a result, the corporation’s profits are first subject to the 35 percent corporate income tax rate, leaving it with $65.00 in after-tax income to distribute as dividends to its shareholders. These dividends are then taxed under the individual income tax at a rate of 23.8 percent, leaving the shareholders with $49.53 in after-tax income.

While these examples are simplified, there is also clear evidence that equity-financed corporate income is subject to a uniquely high tax burden under the current U.S. tax code. In December 2014, the Congressional Budget Office issued a report that found that equity-financed corporate investments are subject to an average effective tax rate of 38 percent. To contrast, equity-financed pass-through business investments are subject to an average effective rate of 30 percent.[7]

The Case for Corporate Integration

In general, there is rarely a good reason for some types of economic activity to be taxed at higher rates than others. In fact, most economists agree that taxing specific segments of the economy at higher rates leads to economic inefficiency, by causing individuals to make choices based on tax considerations, rather than the economic merits.[8] The principle of tax neutrality – that a tax system should neither encourage nor discourage specific economic decisions – is embraced by public policy scholars throughout the political spectrum.[9]

Corporate integration – taxing all business income at the same top rate, regardless of the legal form of the business or how the income was financed – would minimize the economic distortions created by the U.S. tax code and conform to the principle of neutrality. Thus, the burden of proof rests upon those who would seek to tax certain business income at higher rates, to show why the benefits of such a policy would outweigh the accompanying economic harms.

One might assume that there exists a principled rationale for levying a higher tax rate on equity-financed corporate income, given that this has been the case for the past couple decades. In fact, there are few defenders of the status quo. As one law professor puts it,

Corporate income is currently taxed twice… This “double taxation” is a much reviled but stubbornly persistent feature of our current system. Few, if any, commenters suggest that we would consciously adopt it if we were working from a blank slate, and most openly recommend double taxation’s demise.[10]

Some defenders of the double taxation of corporate income argue that it is “the fee that stockholders pay for the benefits of corporate status.”[11] In fact, the evidence is mixed as to whether the burden of corporate taxes is primarily born by shareholders.[12] After all, if investors respond to higher U.S. corporate taxes by shifting their investments to lower-tax countries, their investment returns will barely be harmed, while U.S workers will bear the bulk of the burden. In fact, in a survey of public finance economists, the median respondent thought that only 40 percent of the corporate income tax burden is born by investors.[13]

The lack of convincing arguments for the double taxation of corporate income, combined with the strong presumption that all business income should generally be taxed at the same rate, should be sufficient to show why corporate integration would be highly desirable. Nevertheless, it is also useful to highlight specific economic harms that result from higher taxes on equity-financed corporate income.

Preference for Debt over Equity

When a corporation makes a new investment, it faces a choice between two basic ways of obtaining the necessary up-front cash: debt and equity. When a corporation finances an investment with debt, a debtholder becomes entitled to a stream of fixed payments from the corporation in the future. On the other hand, when a corporation finances an investment with equity, a shareholder becomes entitled to a share of the corporation’s future profits and usually gains the right to vote on matters of corporate policy.

Investors face a complicated choice when determining how much new investment to finance with debt and how much to finance with equity.[14] For instance, the more that a corporation relies on debt financing, the more time and money the corporation may have to waste in bankruptcy proceedings should it default.[15] On the other hand, the more that a corporation relies on equity financing, the more conflicts may arise between managers and shareholders, who often have opposite interests.[16]

There is a large economic literature that discusses the relative merits of debt and equity financing for corporations.[17] Economists generally assume that corporations strive for an “optimal” mix of debt and equity, one that minimizes the disadvantages of each.

However, the U.S. tax code encourages corporations to deviate from the ideal mix of debt and equity. As discussed above, under the current U.S. tax code, equity-financed corporate investment is subject to a top rate of 50.47 percent, while debt-financed corporate investment is subject to a top rate of 43.4 percent. As a result, the tax code incentivizes corporations to take on higher-than-optimal levels of debt.

There is reason to believe that the tax bias towards debt creates harmful macroeconomic consequences. Lower taxes on debt may lead corporations to engage in more risky behavior and increase the chance of firm bankruptcy.[18] Furthermore, there is evidence that recessions caused by debt bubbles are more harmful than those caused by equity bubbles, making the favorable tax treatment of debt even more suspect.[19]

Economists across the political spectrum agree that the corporate tax code’s bias towards debt over equity is harmful.[20] By standardizing business taxation across methods of financing, corporate integration would put an end to this unideal tax preference.

Preference for Non-Corporate Business Forms

Another harmful consequence of the double taxation of corporate income is that it encourages the misallocation of capital among business forms.

The majority of businesses in the United States are not corporations. 32.8 million businesses that filed tax returns in 2012, and only 1.6 million were traditional C corporations. The other 31.2 million were pass-through businesses, such as partnerships, sole proprietorships, and S corporations.[21]

As described above, pass-through businesses do not face any entity-level taxes. Instead, their profits are passed on to individual taxpayers and taxed through the individual income tax code. On the other hand, the profits of C corporations are taxed on both the entity level and the shareholder level. As a result, C corporations typically face higher marginal and effective tax rates than pass-through businesses.[22]

All else being equal, we would expect that these higher tax rates on C corporations will lead to underinvestment in C corporations and overinvestment in pass-through business. In other words, the current business tax code may prevent some investors from making otherwise productive investments in C corporations because of the tax consequences.

Indeed, over the past thirty years, in response to the high tax burden on C corporations, more and more business activity has shifted to pass-through business.[23] In 1980, pass-through businesses only accounted for 20 percent of total business income in the United States. By 2012, 64 percent of net business income was earned by pass-throughs.

Chart 1.

In other words, over the last 35 years, the United States has seen a large reallocation of capital from C corporations to pass-through businesses, due to the high tax burden on C corporations. To the extent that this shift was driven by tax policy, rather than economic fundamentals, the current allocation of capital in the U.S. is likely not as efficient as it could be.

By equalizing tax rates on corporations and pass-through businesses, corporate integration could also lead to more efficient investment across business sectors.

Strategies for Corporate Integration

Over the years, policymakers and economists have proposed several different ways to integrate the corporate and individual tax codes. As a result, there are at least eight distinct tax proposals that fall under the heading of “corporate integration.”[24]

These proposals share several features in common. All of them would standardize the taxation of business income across legal forms and methods of financing. As a result, each would reduce or eliminate the double tax on equity-financed corporate income.

However, corporate integration proposals vary significantly in design. For instance, one way of integrating the corporate and individual tax codes is simply to exclude dividends from shareholder-level taxes altogether (dividend exclusion). Another is to allocate a corporation’s income to its shareholders as it is earned (shareholder allocation).

Below, I highlight two of the most straightforward methods for integrating the corporate and individual tax and describe them in detail. The first (dividends paid deduction) would shift a substantial portion of the corporate income tax to the shareholder level. The second (credit imputation) would move in the opposite direction, reducing taxes paid at the shareholder level.

Dividends Paid Deduction

Perhaps the simplest way to integrate the corporate and individual tax codes would be to tax dividends received by individuals at ordinary income rates and allow corporations to deduct all of their dividends paid.

The table below shows an example of how this would work. The corporation in this example earns $100 in profits and distributes all of its profits as dividends. Because the corporation is able to deduct its dividends paid, it has no taxable incomeTaxable income is the amount of income subject to tax, after deductions and exemptions. For both individuals and corporations, taxable income differs from—and is less than—gross income. and owes no corporate income tax. Meanwhile, the corporation’s shareholders are taxed on their dividends at a top rate of 43.4 percent – the same as the current top tax rate as interest income.

Table 4. The Combined Federal Corporate Tax Rate on Equity-Financed Income, under a Dividends Paid Deduction System

Corporate Income Tax

Individual Income Tax

Corporate profits

$100.00

Dividends paid deduction

-$100.00

Dividends received

$100.00

Corporate taxable income

$0.00

Individual income tax owed (43.4 percent rate)

$43.40

Corporate income tax owed

$0.00

After-tax income

$56.60

Indeed, a dividends paid deduction would make the tax treatment of dividends almost identical to the tax treatment of interest, erasing the tax code’s bias toward debt.[25] It would also put the tax treatment of investments in corporations on par with the tax treatment of investments in pass-through business.

A dividends paid deduction would shift a large portion of the corporate income tax burden onto shareholders. As a result, the chief pitfall in designing a dividends paid deduction is that some shareholders of U.S. corporations are exempt from U.S. taxes on their dividends. To the extent that a dividend paid deduction system could leave some dividend income subject to no additional U.S. taxes, this would reduce federal revenue significantly.

For instance, tax-exempt organizations in the United States are not generally required to pay taxes on the dividends they receive from corporations. Implementing a dividends paid deduction would be a windfall for these organizations: the corporate-level taxes on their investments would drop significantly, while their shareholder-level taxes would remain at zero.[26] Similarly, foreign shareholders of U.S. corporations would see the corporate-level taxes on their investments fall, without paying any additional shareholder-level taxes to the U.S. federal government.

Credit Imputation

Another relatively straight-forward strategy for corporate integration is credit imputation. Under a credit imputation system, both a corporation and its shareholders pay taxes on corporate income, but the shareholders receive a credit for all taxes paid at the corporate level. Notably, this is the method of corporate integration used in Australia and six other countries.[27]

The table below shows how a credit imputation system would work.

  • The corporation in this example earns $100 in profits, pays $35 in corporate income taxes and distributes the remaining $65 in dividends.
  • Then, the corporation’s shareholders pay taxes on the entire $100 of pre-tax corporate profit. In technical terms, the shareholders “gross-up” the dividend from $65 to $100 when including it in their adjusted gross incomeFor individuals, gross income is the total pre-tax earnings from wages, tips, investments, interest, and other forms of income and is also referred to as “gross pay.” For businesses, gross income is total revenue minus cost of goods sold and is also known as “gross profit” or “gross margin.” . [28]
  • Shareholders pay ordinary income tax rates on their grossed-up dividends. For instance, a household in the top income bracket would pay $43.40 in taxes on dividends.
  • Finally, shareholders receive a refundable credit for all corporate income taxes paid. As a result, a household in the top income bracket would owe only $8.40 in taxes on dividends.
Table 5. The Combined Federal Corporate Tax Rate on Equity-Financed Income, under a Credit Imputation System

Corporate Income Tax

Individual Income Tax

Corporate profits

$100.00

Corporate income tax owed

(35 percent rate)

$35.00

Dividends distributed

$65.00

Dividends received

$65.00

Grossed-up dividends

$100.00

Initial individual income tax owed (43.4 percent rate)

$43.40

Credit for corporate taxes paid

-$35.00

Total individual income tax owed

$8.40

After-tax income

$56.60

Credit imputation would nearly eliminate the tax code’s bias towards debt over equity, and would equalize the taxation of corporations and pass-through businesses. This is clear from the example above, where a $100 corporate equity investment faces $43.40 in combined taxes – the same as the tax burden on pass-through business and on corporate debt.

It is useful to note that, under a credit imputation system, every additional dollar that a corporation pays in corporate income taxes means one fewer dollar that its shareholders pay in individual income taxes, and vice versa. For instance, if the corporation in the example above had only paid $25 in corporate income taxes instead of $35, its shareholders would have owed $18.40 in individual income taxes, instead of $8.40.

Conclusion

Corporate integration would not fix all, or even most of the problems with the U.S. business tax system. The United States has one of the highest statutory corporate tax rates in the world, a counter-productive set of rules regarding overseas income, and a cumbersome system of depreciationDepreciation is a measurement of the “useful life” of a business asset, such as machinery or a factory, to determine the multiyear period over which the cost of that asset can be deducted from taxable income. Instead of allowing businesses to deduct the cost of investments immediately (i.e., full expensing), depreciation requires deductions to be taken over time, reducing their value and discouraging investment. and cost recoveryCost recovery is the ability of businesses to recover (deduct) the costs of their investments. It plays an important role in defining a business’ tax base and can impact investment decisions. When businesses cannot fully deduct capital expenditures, they spend less on capital, which reduces worker’s productivity and wages. .[29] Corporate integration would not solve any of these issues.

However, corporate integration could lead to several important incremental improvements to the current U.S. tax code. Corporate integration would lower the combined tax burden on corporate income, which would increase investment and economic growth in the United States. It would eliminate the tax code’s bias in favor of debt over equity, leading to better investment decisions. And it would put corporate investment on par with non-corporate investment, leading to a more efficient allocation of capital.



[1] Bernie Becker, “Hatch to take a shot at corporate double tax,” Politico, January 21, 2016, http://www.politico.com/tipsheets/morning-tax/2016/01/hatch-to-take-a-shot-at-corporate-double-tax-brady-tax-staffer-gets-high-marks-yes-the-irs-deleted-another-key-hard-drive-212275. Kaustuv Basu and Dylan Moroses, “Hatch Corporate Integration Draft Could Be Ready in a Few Months,” Tax Notes, January 29, 2016, http://www.taxnotes.com/tax-notes-today/corporate-taxation/hatch-corporate-integration-draft-could-be-ready-few-months/2016/01/29/18189631.

[2] For a detailed history of corporate integration proposals since the 1970s, see “Comprehensive Tax Reform for 2015 and Beyond,” Senate Finance Committee, http://online.wsj.com/public/resources/documents/Taxes121514.pdf.

[3] Here, and throughout, “corporate” and “corporation” refer to C corporations, unless otherwise specified.

[4] Over the past few decades, lawmakers have taken some steps to equalize the tax treatment of equity-financed corporate income and other business income. Most significantly, the Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003 cut the top federal tax rate on qualified dividends to 15 percent, which significantly reduced the double tax on corporations. However, Congress has never fully eliminated the U.S. tax code’s bias against equity-financed corporate income. Furthermore, in 2013, the top tax rate on dividends rose to 23.8 percent, exacerbating the unfavorable tax treatment of corporate income.

[5] As detailed in “Comprehensive Tax Reform for 2015 and Beyond,” the Treasury Department has issued corporate integration proposals in 1975, January 1977, September 1977, 1984, 1985, and 1992. The White House has issued reports recommending corporate integration in 1985, 2003, 2005, and 2010. Congressional legislators have introduced major corporation integration bills in 1978, 2003.

[6] It may be useful to spell out this logic more explicitly. Under standard economic theory, a business will continue to pursue additional investments as long as the rate of return on these investments exceeds the interest rate. The business’s marginal investment will have an expected rate of return that is the same as the interest rate. This means that a business expects to make as much profit on its marginal investment as it pays in interest. In other words, a business expects that its marginal debt-financed investment does not lead to any additional corporate tax burden, because its interest deduction will be as large as its profits. Thus, under standard economic theory, a corporation’s marginal debt-financed investment is made in the expectation that no entity-level tax will be applied to the profits.

[7] “Taxing Capital Income: Effective Marginal Tax RateThe marginal tax rate is the amount of additional tax paid for every additional dollar earned as income. The average tax rate is the total tax paid divided by total income earned. A 10 percent marginal tax rate means that 10 cents of every next dollar earned would be taken as tax. s Under 2014 Law and Selected Policy Options,” Congressional Budget Office, http://www.cbo.gov/publication/49817

[8] Joel Slemrod, “Optimal Taxation and Optimal Tax Systems,” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 4 (1990): 157-178. Louis Kaplow, “On the Undesirability of Commodity Taxation Even When Income Taxation Is Not Optimal,” Journal of Public Economics 90 (2004): 1235-1250.

[9] See Jason Furman, “The Concept of Neutrality in Tax Policy,” Testimony Before Senate Finance Committee, 2008, http://www.brookings.edu/research/testimony/2008/04/15-tax-neutrality-furman; J.D. Foster, “True Tax Reform: Improves the Economy, Does Not Raise Taxes,” Heritage Foundation, 2011, http://www.heritage.org/research/reports/2011/11/true-tax-reform-improves-the-economy-does-not-raise-taxes

[10] Steven A. Bank, “Corporate Managers, Agency Costs, and the Rise of Double Taxation,” FSU College of Law, Public Law Research Paper No. 45 (2002).

[11] “The Double Taxation of Corporate Profits and Other Fairy Tales,” Center for Economic and Policy Research, 2011, http://cepr.net/blogs/beat-the-press/the-double-taxation-of-corporate-profits-and-other-fairy-tales

[12] Wiliam M. Gentry, “A Review of the Evidence of the Incidence of the Corporate Income Tax,” Treasury Department, OTA Paper 101 (2007). Arnold C. Harberger, “Corporation Tax IncidenceTax incidence is a measure of who ultimately pays a tax, either directly or through the tax burden. This burden can be split between buyers and consumers, or different groups in the economy. : What is Known, Unknown, and Unknowable,” Conference Paper, 2006, http://www.econ.ucla.edu/harberger/ah-corptax4-06.pdf

[13] Victor Fuchs et. al., “Why do Economists Disagree About Policy? The Roles of Beliefs About Parameters and Values,” National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 6151 (1997).

[14] An excellent explanation of some of the considerations in the corporate debt-equity tradeoff can be found in Daniel Shaviro, Decoding the U.S. Corporate Tax, The Urban Institute Press, 2009.

[15] Alan Kraus and Robert Litzenberger, “A State-Preference Model of Optimal Financial Leverage,” The Journal of Finance 28 (1973): 911-922.

[16] Milton Harris and Artur Raviv, “Capital Structure and the Informational Role of Debt,” The Journal of Finance 45 (1990): 321-349.

[17] For an overview of this literature, see Milton Harris and Artur Raviv, “The Theory of Capital Structure,” The Journal of Finance 46 (1991): 297-355.

[18] Dirk Schoenmaker, “Removing tax advantages of debt is vital,” Financial Times, 2010, https://next.ft.com/content/0ab3e042-13bb-11e0-814c-00144feabdc0

[19] Òscar Jordà, “Leveraged Bubbles,” National Bureau of Economic Research, 2015, http://www.nber.org/papers/w21486

[20] Curtis Dubay, “Taxation of Debt and Equity: Setting the Record Straight,” Heritage Foundation, 2015, http://www.heritage.org/research/reports/2015/09/taxation-of-debt-and-equity-setting-the-record-straight; Jared Bernstein, “Happy Tax Day! Now, let’s get to work on that messy tax code of ours,” Washington Post, April 18, 2016, https://www.washingtonpost.com/posteverything/wp/2016/04/18/happy-tax-day-now-lets-get-to-work-on-that-messy-tax-code-of-ours/

[21] For an overview of pass-through businesses and how they are taxed, see Kyle Pomerleau, “An Overview of Pass-through Business Taxation in the United States,” Tax Foundation, 2015, https://taxfoundation.org/article/overview-pass-through-businesses-united-states

[22] On effective rates by business form, see Michael Cooper et. al., “Business in the United States: Who Owns it and How Much Tax Do They Pay?,” National Bureau of Economic Research, 2015, http://www.nber.org/papers/w21651

[23] Congressional Budget Office, “Taxing Businesses Through the Individual Income Tax,” 2012, https://www.cbo.gov/publication/43750

[24] The U.S. Chamber of Commerce has a helpful chart on its website, outlining eight different strategies for corporate integration: http://image.uschamber.com/lib/feed13797d6307/m/1/corporate+tax+integration+methods.pdf

[25] However, there would still be a timing difference in the tax treatment of dividends and interest. Under the current tax code, interest is deducted as it accrues. Meanwhile, a simple dividends paid deduction would allow corporations to deduct dividends according to the cash method.

[26] One solution to this conundrum is simply to tax non-profit organizations on all of their investment income. While highly appealing from a policy perspective, this strategy is probably politically unfeasible.

[27] Kyle Pomerleau, “Eliminating Double Taxation through Corporate Integration,” Tax Foundation, 2015, https://taxfoundation.org/article/eliminating-double-taxation-through-corporate-integration

[28] Importantly, a credit imputation system can create vastly different revenue and economic effects depending on how households are required to gross-up their dividends received.

[29] Alan Cole, “Fixing the Corporate Income Tax,” Tax Foundation, 2016, https://taxfoundation.org/article/fixing-corporate-income-tax

Share