Skip to content

Understanding the House GOP’s Border Adjustment

29 min readBy: Kyle Pomerleau

Key Findings

  • In 2016, the House Republicans released a taxA tax is a mandatory payment or charge collected by local, state, and national governments from individuals or businesses to cover the costs of general government services, goods, and activities. plan that would lower the corporate income taxA corporate income tax (CIT) is levied by federal and state governments on business profits. Many companies are not subject to the CIT because they are taxed as pass-through businesses, with income reportable under the individual income tax. rate to 20 percent and convert it into a “destination-based cash-flow tax.”
  • An important feature of this tax is a “border adjustment.” This provision would apply the tax to imports and exempt exports.
  • The application of the border adjustment moves the corporate income tax from an “origin-based” tax to a “destination-based” tax.
  • Both origin- and destination-based taxes are trade-neutral. As such, switching from one to the other does not alter the trade balance, nor put the United States at a trade advantage or disadvantage.
  • Although economists do not expect there to be a trade advantage to switching to a destination-based tax, there are a few positive aspects of doing so: it would prevent profit shiftingProfit shifting is when multinational companies reduce their tax burden by moving the location of their profits from high-tax countries to low-tax jurisdictions and tax havens. , eliminate the need for complex anti-base erosion provisions, and broaden the tax baseThe tax base is the total amount of income, property, assets, consumption, transactions, or other economic activity subject to taxation by a tax authority. A narrow tax base is non-neutral and inefficient. A broad tax base reduces tax administration costs and allows more revenue to be raised at lower rates. within the budget window.
  • There are also challenges with this approach. It is not known yet whether this provision could be struck down by the World Trade Organization (WTO). In addition, a few implementation and transition challenges may exist.

Introduction

In June 2016, the House Republicans released a comprehensive tax reform plan. The plan proposes to significantly reform the way in which businesses are taxed in the United States by converting the current corporate income tax into a “destination-based cash-flow tax” (DBCFT).

One of the most significant features of this plan is a border adjustment. The border adjustment would eliminate the ability for companies to deduct the cost of imports. At the same time, it would eliminate the tax on income attributable to exports. This would shift the current corporate income tax from an origin-based tax—one that applies to the production of goods and services in the United States—to a destination-based tax—one that applies to the consumption of goods and services in the United States.

This goal of this paper is to explain the role of the border adjustment in the GOP plan and its likely effects. The paper reviews the basics of origin- and destination-based taxes, how they interact with trade, and why economists expect there to be no net impact on the economy or the trade balance from switching from an origin-based tax to a destination-based tax. The paper will also review some positive aspects of the border adjustment as well as some potential challenges with its enactment.

The House GOP’s Destination-Based Cash-flow Tax

In June 2016, the House Republicans released a tax reform plan, titled “A Better Way.” The plan would reform both the individual income taxAn individual income tax (or personal income tax) is levied on the wages, salaries, investments, or other forms of income an individual or household earns. The U.S. imposes a progressive income tax where rates increase with income. The Federal Income Tax was established in 1913 with the ratification of the 16th Amendment. Though barely 100 years old, individual income taxes are the largest source of tax revenue in the U.S. and business taxation in the United States. On the individual side it would lower marginal tax rates on wage, investment, and business income; broaden the tax base; and simplify the tax code. The plan would also lower the corporate income tax rate to 20 percent and make a number of significant changes to its tax base. Finally, the plan would eliminate federal estate and gift taxes.[1]

Arguably, the most significant reform the House GOP’s tax plan makes is to how businesses in the United States are taxed.

The GOP plan would convert the corporate income tax into what is called a “destination-based cash-flow tax.” In order to get to this new tax from the current system, the plan makes four major changes to the business income tax base:

  • Businesses would be able to fully expense their capital investments rather than depreciate them over a number of years or decades.
  • Businesses would no longer be able to deduct their net interest expense against their taxable incomeTaxable income is the amount of income subject to tax, after deductions and exemptions. For both individuals and corporations, taxable income differs from—and is less than—gross income. .
  • Foreign profits would no longer be subject to domestic taxation.
  • The corporate income tax would be “destination-based,” meaning that the plan would make the U.S. income tax border-adjustable.

The stated goals of this reform are to grow the economy, increase the competitiveness of U.S. firms, and simplify the business tax system.[2] In addition, supporters of the plan state that enacting the border adjustment would eliminate the “made in America tax” and increase the competitiveness of U.S. products on world markets.[3]

The Border Adjustment

The most novel change the House GOP plan makes to the current tax code is that it applies the destination principle to the U.S. business income tax. This is done by enacting a “border adjustment.” In the plan, businesses in the United States would no longer be able to deduct the cost of purchases from abroad, or imports. At the same time, businesses would no longer be taxed on the revenue attributable to sales abroad, or exports.

A border adjustment is a relatively new concept in the context of a business income tax. However, border adjustments are very common throughout the world, are natural components of most consumption-based taxes, and date to the 1860s.[4] Many retail sales taxA sales tax is levied on retail sales of goods and services and, ideally, should apply to all final consumption with few exemptions. Many governments exempt goods like groceries; base broadening, such as including groceries, could keep rates lower. A sales tax should exempt business-to-business transactions which, when taxed, cause tax pyramiding. es in the United States are destination-based and have border adjustments, and most value-added taxes (VAT) throughout the world employ border adjustments.

Origin- and Destination-Based Taxes: Two Alternate, Neutral Tax Bases

The most basic way to understand the border adjustment is to understand the change it makes to the business income tax base.

Generally, a country has two options when setting a tax base. It can levy an origin-based tax; a tax on the production of goods and services in a country. Or, a country can levy a destination-based tax; a tax on the sale of goods and services in a country.

An easy way to think about the difference between origin- and destination-based tax systems is to organize goods and services in an economy into three categories: 1) Purely domestic goods and services, those that are both produced and consumed in the U.S.; 2) Goods produced domestically and consumed in foreign countries, or exports; 3) Goods produced in foreign countries and consumed in the U.S., or imports.

Origin-based and destination-based taxes
Origin-based Taxes

An origin based-tax is one that taxes goods based on where they are produced, regardless of where they are consumed. As such, an origin-based tax applies to both goods produced and consumed domestically (purely domestic goods) and to goods produced in the U.S. and consumed in foreign countries (exports). In the two-by-two matrix (below), an origin-based tax is applied to the top and bottom boxes on the left.

Origin-based Tax - Border Adjustment

An origin-based tax is neutral with respect to domestic production. Generally, the current corporate income tax is an origin-based tax: the tax falls on the production of goods in the United States, regardless of where they end up.[5]

Destination-based Taxes

A destination-based tax is one that taxes goods and services based on where they are consumed, regardless of where they are produced. In our two-by-two matrix, a destination-based tax system is levied on goods and services in the two top boxes: goods produced and sold domestically (purely domestic products) and goods produced in foreign countries and sold domestically (imports).

Destination-based taxes

A destination-based tax is neutral with respect to domestic consumption. VATs throughout the world are destination-based. Also, most retail sales taxes are destination-based. Individuals pay state sales taxes on all goods consumed in a state, regardless of where those goods were produced.

A destination-based tax is not the same as a tariffTariffs are taxes imposed by one country on goods or services imported from another country. Tariffs are trade barriers that raise prices and reduce available quantities of goods and services for U.S. businesses and consumers. . As the diagram above shows, a destination-based tax falls on all domestic consumption, whether it is produced in the United States or produced in a foreign country. While a destination-based tax applies to imports, it also falls on domestically produced goods as well. By contrast, a tariff applies only to imports, creating a higher price for traded goods relative to domestic goods. While destination-based taxes are neutral, tariffs are not.

Origin- and Destination-Based Taxes and International Trade

A striking difference between origin-based taxes and destination-based taxes is that they are applied to opposite sides of the trade balance. It appears as though an origin-based tax punishes exports and subsidized imports while a destination-based tax does the opposite.

This view—that origin- and destination-based taxes have different impacts on the trade balance—is wrong. Both an origin-based tax and a destination-based tax are trade-neutral and switching from one to another does not impact the trade balance. This is because exports and imports are two sides of the same coin. Exports are needed to pay for imports and imports are the returns to exports. As such, taxing exports ends up reducing imports and taxing imports ends up reducing exports.

Basics of International Trade

Trade between countries is a positive sum activity. To take a stylized example, when South Korea sells laptop computers to the United States, it is doing so in order to purchase airplanes from the United States. And the United States sells airplanes to South Korea in order to purchase Korean laptops. A balance between imports and exports occurs over the long run because Americans would not trade with Koreans unless they knew they were going to get something in return and vice versa.

In reality, trade doesn’t always net out between two countries in every single year. In some years South Korea may sell more laptops to the United States than the United States sells airplanes to South Korea, or the U.S. may sell more to South Korea than it buys.

Annual trade imbalances are driven by capital flows between countries. When Korea sells goods to the United States, there is a corresponding capital outflow from the U.S. to Korea, as Korea trades its won (currency) for U.S. assets such as dollars, stocks, or bonds. So, if Korea sees additional investment opportunities in the United States, it will sell the U.S. more laptops in order to procure more U.S. assets instead of immediately purchasing more airplanes from the U.S. This inflow of capital to the United States creates a trade deficit, which can persist as long as foreign countries see investment opportunities in the United States.

This relationship among the flows of goods, services, and capital is a basic accounting identity in economics and is true for every country in every year.[6] Countries that run trade surpluses are simultaneously running capital account deficits, because they are saving or investing, on net, in foreign countries. Countries that run trade deficits are simultaneously running capital account surpluses and are receiving net capital inflows.[7]

Simply put, a country’s exports are the price it pays in order to purchase goods from or invest in foreign countries. Likewise, imports are the returns, or income, a country receives from international trade and investment. Increases or decreases in one end up affecting the other.

Origin- and Destination-based Taxes have the Same Impact on Trade

Understanding that imports and exports are two sides of the same coin makes it easy to understand why both an origin- and destination-based tax impact trade in the same way.

An origin-based tax, which falls on exports and exempts imports, ends up reducing imports in the long run. This is because, if the United States does not produce as many exports, it is not able to purchase as many imports.

Similarly, a destination-based tax, which falls directly on imports and exempts exports, ends up reducing exports in the long run. This is because, if foreign countries cannot export as much to the United States, it becomes harder for them to purchase our exported goods.

Assuming both taxes are broad-based and have the same rate, an origin-based and a destination-based tax should impact the tradable sector in the same way, even though one falls on exports and the other falls on imports.

Switching from an Origin-based Tax to a Destination-based Tax: Currency and Price Adjustments

Since an origin-based tax and destination-based tax impact trade in the same way, switching from an origin-based tax to a destination-based tax, such as the GOP proposal would have no net impact on trade. When the border adjustment is applied, either the U.S. dollar would appreciate or the domestic price level would increase, so that imports and domestic goods remain on an equal footing compared to current law.

In general, most economists believe that prices will adjust through changes in nominal exchange rates.[8] Specifically, the dollar would appreciate relative to foreign currencies to eliminate the change in prices created by the border adjustment. As such, foreign imports would cost precisely as much as they do, net of tax, under current law in the United States. And U.S. exports would cost precisely as much as they do, net of tax, under current law in foreign markets.[9]

The intuition behind this is pretty simple. Changes to the trade of goods and services correspond to changes in the trade of currencies. This is because individuals need currencies in order to purchase goods in services in the world market. So, changing supply or demand for imports and exports through taxation should have a corresponding impact on the supply and demand for currencies.[10] A switch to a destination-based tax would simultaneously boost the demand and reduce the supply for U.S. dollars, causing an appreciation of the U.S. currency.[11]

Alternatively, if currencies do not or cannot adjust, the domestic price level would adjust to eliminate the price differential between imports and domestic products. In a case without any currency adjustment, the initial swap to a destination-based tax would create a temporary price differential between domestic and foreign goods. This price differential would increase demand for domestic goods and lower demand for foreign goods and would shift economic activity towards domestic goods. Over time, this would drive up domestic prices and wages, which would eventually equalize the price of foreign and domestic goods.[12] However, this outcome is very unlikely in a country like the United States, which has flexible exchange rates.

Economic Literature and Empirical Evidence on Border Adjustments

An important empirical question is whether the swap from an origin-based tax to a destination-based tax would result in a quick adjustment to the exchange rate, or a more gradual adjustment through domestic prices.

Most economic literature dating to the 1950s agrees on the theory that destination-based taxes are fundamentally trade-neutral and that border adjustments do not afford a trade advantage or change the balance of trade. Most literature also agrees that theoretically, prices change mainly through adjustments in exchange rates.[13]

Surprisingly, there has been little empirical work done on the matter. One paper looked specifically at how VATs impacted trade and found that the use of border-adjusted VATs in countries was associated with lower trade. However, this paper did not answer the question of how prices are impacted by a border adjustment, and the authors believe that the trade impact was due to imperfect border adjustments rather than the policy itself. [14]

While very little empirical work has been done specifically on how border adjustments impact exchange rates and prices, some related empirical work is helpful in understanding the likely effects of enacting a border adjustment.

Some studies imply that, in countries with flexible exchange rates, the application of a border adjustment would result in a quick appreciation of the domestic currency. These studies have focused on “fiscal devaluations,” which is when a country simultaneously cuts its employer-side payroll taxA payroll tax is a tax paid on the wages and salaries of employees to finance social insurance programs like Social Security, Medicare, and unemployment insurance. Payroll taxes are social insurance taxes that comprise 24.8 percent of combined federal, state, and local government revenue, the second largest source of that combined tax revenue. and raises its border-adjusted VAT. [15] This work found that in countries with exchange rates that are inflexible with most of their trading partners, such as those in the Euro Zone, the border adjustment resulted in a temporary domestic stimulus, which implies that the increase in a border-adjusted tax was passed along into higher domestic prices and wages. However, this work did not find the same effect in countries with more flexible exchange rates, implying that exchange rates adjusted rapidly in those countries to offset the new, or higher, border adjustment. [16]

At the same time, literature on “exchange rate pass-through,” which is essentially the extent to which adjustments in nominal exchange rates are translated into domestic prices. This work shows that changes in exchange rates may not immediately translate into lower domestic prices and may result in the tax being passed-through to consumers or producers in the short run. This is due to goods being priced in a common currency or pricing contracts that are fixed over some time.[17]

Advantages of a Border Adjustment

Although an origin-based and destination-based tax are economically equivalent in terms of their impact on trade, there are actually some non-economic advantages that may make the switch to a destination-based tax worthwhile. Paired with other aspects of a DBCFT, the border adjustment would make many strategies of profit shifting under current law impossible. It would also be possible to lift some of the complex anti-base erosion provisions that typically come with origin-based tax systems. Lastly, a border adjustment in a DBCFT raises a significant amount of revenue in the budget window, which can be used to finance other important reforms such as full expensingFull expensing allows businesses to immediately deduct the full cost of certain investments in new or improved technology, equipment, or buildings. It alleviates a bias in the tax code and incentivizes companies to invest more, which, in the long run, raises worker productivity, boosts wages, and creates more jobs. and lower marginal tax rateThe marginal tax rate is the amount of additional tax paid for every additional dollar earned as income. The average tax rate is the total tax paid divided by total income earned. A 10 percent marginal tax rate means that 10 cents of every next dollar earned would be taken as tax. s.

Eliminates Current Law Profit Shifting Techniques

One advantage of a destination-based tax over an origin-based tax is that destination-based taxes prevent the type of profit shifting that erodes the tax base under our corporate income tax. This is because a destination-based tax basically ignores the types of transactions that make profit shifting possible.

Under current law, a company that imports $60 worth of goods from a foreign subsidiary can deduct those costs against taxable income in the United States. If that subsidiary is in a lower tax jurisdiction than the United States, it has an incentive to overprice the import it sells to the U.S. parent company. This shifts profits from the United States to the lower tax jurisdiction. Likewise, a company that exports from the United States to a subsidiary in a lower-tax jurisdiction has the incentive to underprice the export it charges its subsidiary. Both of these maneuvers reduce the worldwide tax burden of the corporation and reduce revenue collections in the United States.

Under a destination-based system, the transactions that allow a reduction in tax liability through profit shifting are eliminated. Since the cost of imports cannot be deducted, it doesn’t matter what a company charges itself; it cannot deduct its import cost and thus cannot change its domestic tax liability. Likewise, exports are excluded from taxable income, so a company charging itself $1 or $1 billion for an export has no bearing on its U.S. tax liability.

The destination-based tax also neutralizes other profit-shifting strategies. Placing intellectual property (IP) in foreign countries and overcharging your domestic operations in order to shift profits no longer works, because royalty payments—the cost of importing IP—are no longer deductible. Likewise, the DBCFT eliminates the net interest expense deduction, which eliminates the benefit of loading up domestic corporations with debt in order to strip the tax base through interest deductions.

In fact, the incentives would go the other way under this tax system. Profit shifting will not change a company’s U.S. tax liability, but it would still change its foreign tax liability. As such, companies would have an incentive to locate profits in the United States. These profits would not be taxed in a foreign jurisdiction nor would they be taxed in the United States. This could have a slight positive economic benefit to the extent that companies shift real activity to the United States along with their profits.

Some have argued that tax avoidance may still be possible under a destination-based business tax.[18] For the most part, these examples of profit shifting are ways in which companies can strip the tax base of foreign countries. While there is a legitimate debate over whether the United States should change its business base from domestic production to domestic consumption, it is not clear why we should care about the tax base of foreign countries.

A legitimate issue of tax avoidance is the issue with direct cross-border business-to-consumer sales, especially of services and digital goods.[19] Unless addressed, a foreign software company could sell its software directly to a customer in the United States. In this case, there is no business that is denied a deduction, and the tax could be avoided.

Simplifies Many Aspects of the Corporate Tax and Eliminates Need for Complex Anti-Base Erosion Provisions

As a result of a destination-based tax’s impact on profit shifting, it is not necessary to apply the anti-base erosion rules that usually come with origin-based tax systems, which would allow for much simpler tax system.

One common goal of tax reform is to move from the current worldwide tax systemA worldwide tax system for corporations, as opposed to a territorial tax system, includes foreign-earned income in the domestic tax base. As part of the 2017 Tax Cuts and Jobs Act (TCJA), the United States shifted from worldwide taxation towards territorial taxation. to a territorial tax systemA territorial tax system for corporations, as opposed to a worldwide tax system, excludes profits multinational companies earn in foreign countries from their domestic tax base. As part of the 2017 Tax Cuts and Jobs Act (TCJA), the United States shifted from worldwide taxation towards territorial taxation. . Although a territorial tax system, which exempts foreign-source income from domestic taxation, is superior to current law, which requires corporations to pay tax on their worldwide profits, it does suffer from base erosion concerns. A company that successfully shifts profits out of the U.S. and repatriates those profits tax-free can reduce their U.S. tax burden. Nearly all developed countries that have territorial tax systems have rules that prevent gaming, and some are much stricter than the current rules in place in the United States.[20]

In a sense, the House GOP proposal uses the border adjustment as an anti-base erosion provision instead of enacting stricter base erosion rules as part of the switch to a territorial tax system. However, some rules would still need to be defined in order to prevent tax avoidance that is possible under destination-based tax systems.

Broadens the Tax Base and Pays for Other Pro-Growth Reforms

Another advantage of the border adjustment is that, over the budget window, the border adjustment raises more than $1 trillion in revenue with relatively little economic harm and in a relatively progressive fashion, meaning it falls most heavily on high-income taxpayers.[21] In the House GOP plan, this revenue is used to finance other provisions, such as full expensing of capital investment and a lower rate on corporate income, which would significantly boost the long-run size of the economy.[22]

The reason the border adjustment raises revenue over the budget window is that, currently, the United States is running a trade deficit. This means that imports, which are taxed under a destination-based tax, exceed exports, which are exempt. Currently, the trade deficit is roughly $500 billion on an annual basis. The Tax Foundation and other organizations estimate that the border adjustment would raise about $1 trillion over the next decade.[23]

It should be noted, however, that this boost in revenue is not permanent. Over an infinite horizon, a border adjustment theoretically raises no revenue in present value terms. Today, the United States imports more than it exports, meaning that border adjustment raises revenue, but in the future the United States could begin to run a trade surplus. If so, the border adjustment will lose revenue from this provision.[24] However, it is not clear whether the United States will begin running a trade surplus any time soon, especially since U.S. assets are still very attractive throughout the world and the dollar remains the world reserve currency.

Challenges with a Border Adjustment

Although the destination-based tax proposed by the House GOP has positive qualities, there are potential challenges with this approach. Specifically, it is not yet clear whether it will comply with WTO rules. In addition, the plan in its current form may not properly treat exporters, meaning that they could be overtaxed in some situations. Lastly, the plan could have some transition costs worth considering.

The World Trade Organization and Foreign Reaction

Probably the most significant challenge the House GOP’s DBCFT faces is the rules of the World Trade Organization. Although there is no economic reason to think the border-adjustment in the tax plan would give the United States an unfair trade advantage, it could still be perceived that way by the current WTO rules.

Generally, WTO rules allow for border adjustments on imports and exports, but under specific circumstances. First, a border adjustment is typically allowed under an indirect taxAn indirect tax is imposed on one person or group, like manufacturers, then shifted to a different payer, usually the consumer. Unlike direct taxes, indirect taxes are levied on goods and services, not individual payers, and collected by the retailer or manufacturer. Sales and Value-Added Taxes (VATs) are two examples of indirect taxes. , like an excise taxAn excise tax is a tax imposed on a specific good or activity. Excise taxes are commonly levied on cigarettes, alcoholic beverages, soda, gasoline, insurance premiums, amusement activities, and betting, and typically make up a relatively small and volatile portion of state and local and, to a lesser extent, federal tax collections. or credit-invoice VAT and not a direct taxA direct tax is levied on individuals and organizations and cannot be shifted to another payer. Often with a direct tax, such as the personal income tax, tax rates increase as the taxpayer’s ability to pay increases, resulting in what’s called a progressive tax. such as a corporate income tax.[25] Second, a tax with a border adjustment needs to treat domestic and foreign goods equally to avoid discrimination against imports. Third, exports cannot receive a larger tax rebate (or exemption) than the tax levied (or otherwise due) on the same goods if they were intended for the domestic market.[26]

It is unclear whether countries would challenge the House GOP plan on the issue of direct vs. indirect taxation, especially since Japan’s VAT with a border adjustment, which could be considered a direct tax, has gone unchallenged since its inception in the early 1990s.[27]

However, the tax, as currently designed, would face a higher risk of a WTO challenge on the grounds that it discriminates against imports in favor of the same domestic goods. Under a typical VAT, domestic goods and foreign goods are treated identically and face full tax on their value added at every point in the value chain. Under the House GOP plan, this would not be the case. Companies that produce in the United States would not be taxed on all of their value added, because they would be able to deduct their wages paid to U.S. employees; by contrast, the full value of foreign goods sold in the United States would be taxed.

This issue isn’t relevant in terms of how the House GOP plan would impact trade from an economic perspective, but it is still a serious legal issue. Allowing a wage deduction against a border-adjusted VAT (essentially equivalent to the House GOP plan) is the same as a country raising a VAT and simultaneously cutting the employer-side payroll tax. WTO rules permit these two simultaneous changes, but the WTO probably wouldn’t analyze the impact of the DBCFT in the context of a country’s entire tax system. Instead, the WTO would likely examine only the DBCFT’s tax burden on an imported product and a domestic like product, as used by identical corporations, at various points in the value chain.

It is not clear whether the final proposal would run into these issues. Some argue that there is not yet enough detail on the plan to determine whether it violates the United States’ WTO obligations.[28] Even if the WTO ruled in favor of the House GOP plan, many countries would have the incentive to apply stricter anti-base erosion provisions and name America a tax haven because foreign companies would attempt to shift profits into the United States as a means to avoid foreign taxes.

Implementation Challenges

As with any new tax system, there are also questions remaining about the plan’s implementation which could have an impact on how well the border adjustment works. Two major issues are making sure exports get a full rebate and that all imports are subject to tax.

In order for a border adjustment to work, the amount of tax paid on imports needs to be directly offset with an exemption of equal size for exports. Under a typical credit-invoice VAT, an exporter gets a full tax creditA tax credit is a provision that reduces a taxpayer’s final tax bill, dollar-for-dollar. A tax credit differs from deductions and exemptions, which reduce taxable income, rather than the taxpayer’s tax bill directly. for VAT paid on exports, which can sometimes result in negative tax liabilities.

It is possible that the GOP DBCFT won’t work the same way. The current proposal provides companies with an income exclusion for exports. For companies with profits, this exclusion would act just like the credit provided by most VATs. For companies with little or no profits, however, this income exclusion will generate a net operating loss (NOL) that the company would need to carry forward into future years.[29] The House GOP plan does propose to allow companies to carry their net operating losses forward for an unlimited period of time and adjust them annually for a real return on capital and inflationInflation is when the general price of goods and services increases across the economy, reducing the purchasing power of a currency and the value of certain assets. The same paycheck covers less goods, services, and bills. It is sometimes referred to as a “hidden tax,” as it leaves taxpayers less well-off due to higher costs and “bracket creep,” while increasing the government’s spending power. , meaning that the losses would never lose their value. However, this could still be problematic. Some exporters may never have taxable income against which to deduct these losses, thus never receiving a refund, which could put exporters at a competitive disadvantage.

One solution to this issue would be to allow companies to get immediate refunds on their losses. This way, companies would be able to receive the cash benefit of the export rebate immediately. The downside of this approach is that it requires the Treasury to potentially write checks to highly profitable companies. A second possibility could be to allow companies to sell NOLs. Exporters could get an immediate benefit for their exports while providing deductions for companies that could use them.

Another challenge is making sure all imports are subject to the border adjustment. The goal of the border adjustment is to make sure that the sales of all goods and services in the United States are taxed, including goods and services sold to consumers. It can be challenging to make sure that direct foreign sales to consumers are taxed, because there is no entity that is denied a deduction for the import.

Some have suggested either requiring consumers or foreign companies to remit the tax.[30] The first would likely present political and compliance problems. The second would require foreign companies to register to pay tax in the United States and may have some administrative challenges.[31]

Transitional Impacts and Trade-offs

As with any major tax reform there are always trade-offs and transitional impacts to consider.

The first issue is the speed at which prices adjust to the transition to a destination-based tax. Theoretically, whether nominal exchange rates adjust or domestic prices adjust, the result ends up neutral and consumers are not impacted. As discussed above, the literature suggests that exchange rates would adjust, but it could take time for that to translate through prices. As a result, the tax could fall on consumers and producers in the short run.

However, it is too early in the tax reform debate to assume any particular short-run impact of the plan. This is because it is unclear what transition rules would be part of the House GOP proposal. For example, lawmakers could phase in the border adjustment over a number of years. The downside of this, however, is it would reduce the provision’s effectiveness as a base broadener.

A consequence of applying the border adjustment and switching to a DBCFT is that foreign assets held by Americans would decline in value. The appreciation of the dollar due to the implementation of the border adjustment would make assets denominated in foreign currencies less valuable. For example, an individual with an investment that yields returns in Euros would find that those returns net fewer dollars after the appreciation. According to one estimate, the one-time devaluation of the stock of this wealth would be roughly $2.4 trillion.[32] At the same time, foreigners who own U.S. assets would receive a windfall as their U.S. dollar profits increase.

It is important to note that while this hit to wealth due to the border adjustment is real, the broader GOP plan would permanently boost Americans’ incomes at the same time.

Another consequence of dollar appreciation is that debts denominated in U.S. dollars will become more expensive in foreign countries. This is because a foreign country or business would need to raise money in the local currency and convert it into more expensive dollars to pay the debt. Emerging markets may be hit hardest by this.[33] However, many policy changes in the United States and natural movements in the market have impacts on the value of the U.S. dollar that could impact dollar-denominated debts.[34] It isn’t clear why a border adjustment would be a special case.

Conclusion

The House GOP proposal to convert the corporate income tax into a “destination-based cash-flow tax” would be a significant departure from how the United States currently taxes businesses. It would essentially eliminate the tax wedgeA tax wedge is the difference between total labor costs to the employer and the corresponding net take-home pay of the employee. It is also an economic term that refers to the economic inefficiency resulting from taxes. on new investment and eliminate many distortions inherent in our current system. However, most people are paying more attention to the border adjustment, which would move the U.S. income tax to a destination-basis.

Some commentators believe that a border adjustment would either be a boon to U.S. production or a detriment to consumers. Yet, economic theory shows that this particular aspect of the plan will have a limited-to-no long-run economic impact.

Although there are no expected trade-related economic gains from implementing a border adjustment, there are advantages to this approach, especially in limiting tax avoidance and simplifying certain aspects of the code. This approach would also raise potential challenges with trade partners, implementation, and transition. However, overall, it is a serious policy worthy of consideration.

Stay informed on the tax policies impacting you.

Subscribe to get insights from our trusted experts delivered straight to your inbox.

Subscribe

[1] Kyle Pomerleau, “Details and Analysis of the 2016 House Republican Tax Reform Plan.” http://taxfoundation.org/details-and-analysis-2016-house-republican-tax-reform-plan

[2] “A Better Way, Our Vision for a Confident America: Tax.” House GOP. June 24, 2016. https://abetterway.speaker.gov/_assets/pdf/ABetterWay-Tax-PolicyPaper.pdf

[3] “Ending the ‘Made in America’ Tax: Three Major Wins for the American People.” https://waysandmeans.house.gov/ending-made-america-tax-three-major-wins-american-people/ and Ernest Christian, “As Tax Reform Goes, So Goes the Nation.” Investor’s Business Daily. http://www.investors.com/politics/commentary/as-tax-reform-goes-so-goes-the-nation/

[4]Consumption TaxA consumption tax is typically levied on the purchase of goods or services and is paid directly or indirectly by the consumer in the form of retail sales taxes, excise taxes, tariffs, value-added taxes (VAT), or an income tax where all savings is tax-deductible. Trends 2016.” Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development. November 30, 2016 http://www.oecd.org/tax/consumption/consumption-tax-trends-19990979.htm; William P. Orzechowski, “Border Tax Adjustments and Fundamental Tax Reform.” Tax Foundation Special Report. November 1, 2001 https://taxfoundation.org/border-tax-adjustments-and-fundamental-tax-reform/

[5] The U.S. corporate income tax deviates from a pure origin-based tax by subjecting foreign profits to domestic taxation. This in effect also partially taxes imports and goods produced and consumers in foreign countries.

[6] One can readily see this in the data. On net the United States ran a trade deficit of $477 billion in 2015. This trade deficit in goods and services was matched with capital inflows of $477 billion in the same year.

[7] This relationship can be formalized as M – X = I – S where M are imports and X are exports. I is net foreign income or capital inflows and S is net foreign saving or capital outflows.

[8] Alan Viard, “Border Tax Adjustments Won’t Stimulate Exports.” AEI. March 2, 2009. https://www.aei.org/publication/border-tax-adjustments-wont-stimulate-exports/

[9] Kyle Pomerleau “Exchange Rates and the Border Adjustment,” Tax Foundation. December 15, 2016. https://taxfoundation.org/exchange-rates-and-border-adjustment/

[10] Alan Cole, “A Beginner’s Guide to Trade and Foreign Exchange.” Tax Foundation. January 9, 2017. https://taxfoundation.org/beginner-s-guide-trade-and-foreign-exchange/

[11] Of course, the real world is more complicated than the simple textbook model. Some countries peg their currencies to the U.S. dollar, so supply and demand for their currencies has little impact on their value. Other countries actually use dollars as their domestic currency. Although these issues complicate the model, price adjustments still occur. Countries that peg will either re-peg to keep their currency in the same position relative to non-dollar currencies, or eventually their domestic price level will change. Similarly, countries that use the dollar would also eventually see a change in their price level. See: Alan Viard, “Border Tax Adjustments Won’t Stimulate Exports.” AEI. March 2, 2009. https://www.aei.org/publication/border-tax-adjustments-wont-stimulate-exports/

[12] Alan Auerbach, Michael Devereux, Michael Keen, John Vella, “Destination-Based Cash Flow Taxation.” Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation. January 27, 2017. http://www.sbs.ox.ac.uk/sites/default/files/Business_Taxation/Docs/Publications/Working_Papers/Series_17/WP1701b.pdf

[13] European Coal and Steel Community, High Authority, “Report on the problems raised by the different turnover tax systems within the Common Market” (Tinbergen Report) (European Coal and Steel Community, High Authority, 1953).
Shibata, Hirofumi, “The theory of economic unions: A comparative analysis of customs unions, free trade areas, and tax unions,” in Carl S. Shoup ed., Fiscal harmonization in common markets, Vol. l: Theory (New York: Columbia University Press, 1967), 145-264.
Johnson, Harry and Mel Krauss, “Border taxes, border tax adjustments, comparative advantage, and the balance of payments.” Canadian Journal of Economics, November 1970, 3 (4), 595-602.
Meade, James E., “A note on border-tax adjustments.” Journal of Political Economy, September-October 1974, 82 (5), 1013-1015.
Floyd, Robert H., “Some long-run implications of border tax adjustments for factor taxes.”
Quarterly Journal of Economics, November 1977, 91 (4), 555-578.
Grossman, Gene M., “Border tax adjustments: Do they distort trade?” Journal of International Economics, February 1980, 10 (1), 117-128.
Feldstein, Martin and Paul Krugman, “International trade effects of value-added taxation,” in Assaf Razin and Joel Slemrod eds., Taxation in the global economy (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1990), 263-278.
Alan Auerbach, “The Future of Fundamental Tax Reform.” The American Economic Review. May 1997.

[14] Mihir A. Desai and James R. Hines Jr., “Value-added Taxes and International Trade: The Evidence.” January 2005. https://www.law.umich.edu/centersandprograms/lawandeconomics/workshops/Documents/Fall2005/hines.pdf

[15] Alan Auerbach, Michael Devereux, Michael Keen, John Vella, “Destination-Based Cash Flow Taxation.” Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation. January 27, 2017. http://www.sbs.ox.ac.uk/sites/default/files/Business_Taxation/Docs/Publications/Working_Papers/Series_17/WP1701b.pdf

[16] Ruud de Mooij and Michael Keen, “‘Fiscal Devaluation’ and Fiscal Consolidation: The VAT in Troubled Times.” IMF Working Paper. https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2012/wp1285.pdf and Emmanuel Fahri, Gita Gopinath, and Oleg Itskhoki, “Border Tax and the US Dollar.” http://www.afr.com/opinion/columnists/border-tax-and-the-us-dollar-20170130-gu1yj0

[17] Gita Gopinath, “The International Price System.” Harvard University and NBER. November 2, 2015. http://scholar.harvard.edu/files/gopinath/files/paper_083115_01.pdf

[18] Reuven S. Avi-Yonah and Kimberly Clausing, “Problems with Destination-Based Corporate Taxes and the Ryan Blueprint.” https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2884903

[19] Ibid

[20] Kyle Pomerleau, “2016 International Tax Competitiveness Index,” Tax Foundation. https://taxfoundation.org/2016-international-tax-competitiveness-index

[21] Kyle Pomerleau, “What is the Distributional Impact of a Destination-Based Cash-Flow Tax?” Tax Foundation. https://taxfoundation.org/what-distributional-impact-destination-based-cash-flow-tax

[22] Kyle Pomerleau, “Details and Analysis of the 2016 House Republican Tax Reform Plan.” Tax Foundation. July 5, 2016.

[23] Kyle Pomerleau, “Details and Analysis of the 2016 House Republican Tax Reform Plan.” Tax Foundation. July 5, 2016. James R. Nunns, Leonard E. Burman, Jeffrey Rohaly, Joseph Rosenberg, Benjamin R. Page, “An Analysis of the House GOP Tax Plan.” Tax Policy Center. September 16, 2016.

[24] “What Would a Cash Flow Tax Look Like For U.S. Companies? Lessons from a Historical Panel.” Office of Tax Analysis Working Paper 116, Page 14. January 2017. https://www.treasury.gov/resource-center/tax-policy/tax-analysis/Documents/WP-116.pdf

[25] “Consumption Tax Trends 2016,” Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development. November 30, 2016 http://www.oecd.org/tax/consumption/consumption-tax-trends-19990979.htm

[26] Scott S. Lincicome and Richard Eglin, “Border-Adjustable Taxes under the WTO Agreements.” White & Case http://www.whitecase.com/publications/alert/border-adjustable-taxes-under-wto-agreements

[27] “Consumption Tax Trends 2016,” Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development. November 30, 2016 http://www.oecd.org/tax/consumption/consumption-tax-trends-19990979.htm

[28] Scott S. Lincicome and Richard Eglin, “Border-Adjustable Taxes under the WTO Agreements.” White & Case http://www.whitecase.com/publications/alert/border-adjustable-taxes-under-wto-agreements

[29] The House GOP blueprint has proposed eliminating NOL carrybacks.

[30] Alan Auerbach, Michael Devereux, Michael Keen, John Vella, “Destination-Based Cash Flow Taxation.” Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation. January 27, 2017. http://www.sbs.ox.ac.uk/sites/default/files/Business_Taxation/Docs/Publications/Working_Papers/Series_17/WP1701b.pdf

[31] Ibid

[32] Emmanuel Fahri, Gita Gopinath, and Oleg Itskhoki, “Border Tax and the US Dollar.” http://www.afr.com/opinion/columnists/border-tax-and-the-us-dollar-20170130-gu1yj0. This is a figure net of liabilities. U.S. debts will now be easier to pay off with a stronger U.S. dollar.

[33] Stan Veuger, “How Border Adjustment Could Trigger a Series of Emerging Market Crises.” AEI http://www.aei.org/publication/how-border-adjustment-could-trigger-a-series-of-emerging-market-crises/

[34] The dollar has appreciated by more than 20 percent in the last two years. This has the exact same impact on dollars-denominated-debts as a policy change that increases the value of the U.S. dollar.

Share