Skip to content

Chamber’s Donohue Takes Unfair Heat for Inequality Skepticism

2 min readBy: Scott Hodge

Thomas J. Donohue, CEO of the U.S. Chamber of Commerce, came under fire in this morning’s Washington Post for sounding like a skeptic on the issue of income inequality.

While the Post may find such skepticism newsworthy, so too should the inequality data recently released by the Congressional Budget Office which clearly suggests that Donohue has a case. No matter if we measure inequality on a pre-tax basis or post-taxA tax is a mandatory payment or charge collected by local, state, and national governments from individuals or businesses to cover the costs of general government services, goods, and activities. basis, it appears that inequality today is less than it was during the last two years of the Clinton administration and only slightly greater than the average level over the past thirty years.

The chart below shows the level of inequality in America from 1979 to 2010 as measured by the Gini Index. This index measures the relative distribution of income between groups of households on a scale of 0 to 1. A measurement of zero means that income is distributed perfectly equally across all households, while a measurement of 1 would indicate that income is concentrated entirely at the top.

As we can see, while inequality has gone through peaks and valleys over the past three decades, it has tended to stay within a fairly narrow range—between 0.400 and 0.500—and has largely tracked the business cycle. In 2010, the Gini Index for pre-tax income stood at 0.474, just 5 percent above the thirty year average of 0.451. The pattern for post-tax income is the same. This is hardly the sign of a radical shift in inequality.

The peaks have typically been during times when the economy was booming or in a bubble (such as in 1986, 2000, 2007), while the valleys have come during weak economic times (such as 1979-1982, 1991, 2001-2002, and 2008-2009).

Cynically speaking, those who think inequality is a bad thing should like recessions because they reduce income inequality and hate boom times because they make us less equal. In reality, the underlying data shows that the wellbeing of all Americans improves with economic growth and sinks for everyone during the bad times.

Objectively, the data supports Donohue’s basic message that policy should be less concerned about the narrow goal of closing inequality and more focused on broader goal of promoting economic growth as a means of lifting the poor up from poverty.

[[{“type”:”media”,”view_mode”:”media_original”,”fid”:”13982″,”attributes”:{“alt”:””,”class”:”media-image”,”height”:”489″,”typeof”:”foaf:Image”,”width”:”571″}}]]

Gini Index for Household Income,
1979 to 2010
Inequality of Before-Tax Income Inequality of After-Tax Income
1979 0.397 0.358
1980 0.400 0.362
1981 0.404 0.370
1982 0.410 0.382
1983 0.424 0.397
1984 0.429 0.405
1985 0.435 0.410
1986 0.456 0.433
1987 0.439 0.408
1988 0.454 0.424
1989 0.447 0.417
1990 0.438 0.410
1991 0.431 0.401
1992 0.439 0.408
1993 0.436 0.400
1994 0.436 0.398
1995 0.441 0.401
1996 0.453 0.412
1997 0.463 0.424
1998 0.469 0.429
1999 0.478 0.438
2000 0.492 0.452
2001 0.463 0.423
2002 0.455 0.416
2003 0.463 0.426
2004 0.476 0.439
2005 0.490 0.452
2006 0.495 0.457
2007 0.500 0.465
2008 0.482 0.444
2009 0.465 0.426
2010 0.474 0.434
Average 1979 to 2010 0.451 0.416
Average 1980 to 2010 0.464 0.426
Source: Congressional Budget Office.
Share this article