Skip to content

Not All Government Spending is Keynesian Stimulus

3 min readBy: William McBride

As governments around the world embark on austerity budgets, many Keynesians and other fans of big spending seek comfort in the words of Keynes himself:

“The boom, not the slump, is the right time for austerity at the Treasury.”

Unfortunately, they fail to recognize that not all spending is the same in this regard. That is, certain kinds of government spending are more effective as stimulus, e.g. investments in infrastructure, roads, airports, etc.

This was what Keynes had in mind when he called for counter-cyclical fiscal policy to combat the Great Depression. At that time, the vast majority of government spending was either investment or consumption, with a relatively small share devoted to transfer payments such as retirement benefits.

The following chart, based on BEA data, shows that in 1937, the year Keynes wrote the words above, transfer payments made up 14 percent of all government spending (federal, state, and local). Transfer payments have more than tripled since then to 44 percent in 2010, mainly as a result of the ballooning triumvirate of Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid. Beginning in 1990, transfer payments step up with each recessionA recession is a significant and sustained decline in the economy. Typically, a recession lasts longer than six months, but recovery from a recession can take a few years. , reflecting increasingly generous unemployment insurance compensation.

taxfoundation.org/files/UserFiles/Image/Blog/transfer_payments_since_Depression.jpg” width=”525″ height=”332″ border=”0″ />

This should be alarming to any self-respecting Keynesian, as well as anyone who likes economic growth, jobs, etc. For the most part, transfer payments amount to taking money away from working people and giving it to non-working people, i.e. paying people to not work. As such, whatever the merits of a social safety net, we should not be surprised to find the tradeoff is lower growth.

It therefore stands to reason that cutting transfer payments may actually increase growth, and this is precisely what the IMF finds in their analysis of 170 cases of fiscal consolidation, i.e. periods of spending cuts and taxA tax is a mandatory payment or charge collected by local, state, and national governments from individuals or businesses to cover the costs of general government services, goods, and activities. hikes, over the last 30 years. The following chart indicates that cuts to transfer payments have statistically zero effect on short term growth, and the point estimate indicates these cuts actually stimulate growth. Cuts to government consumption and investment produce the standard Keynesian result of lower short term growth.

However, IMF simulations of the long term, i.e. when we’re all dead according to Keynes, indicate that debt reduction significantly increases growth — a 10 percentage point drop in debt-to-GDP raises output by 1.4 percent.

The main result of this IMF study, very much in line with other recent research, is that spending-based consolidations are less damaging to short term growth than are tax-based consolidations. In fact, as the following chart shows, they find spending cuts have no (statistically significant) effect on growth in the short term, whereas tax increases significantly and substantially reduce growth.

Part, but not all, of this appears to be explained by offsetting monetary stimulus:

“Fiscal contraction that relies on spending cuts tends to have smaller contractionary effects than tax-based adjustments. This is partly because central banks usually provide substantially more stimulus following a spending-based contraction than following a tax-based contraction. Monetary stimulus is particularly weak following indirect taxAn indirect tax is imposed on one person or group, like manufacturers, then shifted to a different payer, usually the consumer. Unlike direct taxes, indirect taxes are levied on goods and services, not individual payers, and collected by the retailer or manufacturer. Sales and Value-Added Taxes (VATs) are two examples of indirect taxes. hikes (such as the value-added tax, VAT) that raise prices.”

In other words, smart countries, when faced with a debt crisis, cut spending and offset it with monetary stimulus. And the really smart ones focus spending cuts on transfer payments. This is the balance we should be seeking, as opposed to our current political “balance” between spending cuts and tax increases.

Share